Propagation of the global food crisis to the national level is however far from straightforward

The agriculture-based countries have, by definition, a high share of total poverty in the rural sector and a high share of GDP growth originating in agriculture, the latter fundamentally because agriculture accounts for a large share of GDP. They include all the SS-Africa countries else than South Africa as a transforming country and some mineral-rich countries. The current role of agriculture in the development of these countries is not only for industrialization and for economic diversification away from agriculture . Instead, in the emerging paradigm, agriculture has multiple functions for the development of these countries in helping trigger growth at early stages, reduce poverty, increase food security, equalize gender status, reduce ruralurban income disparities, conserve resources, and provide environmental services. These multiple functions can be win-win, but more generally imply trade-offs and the consequent need for country-level priority setting in deciding how to effectively use agriculture for development.Agricultural growth in SS-Africa has been lagging relative to other regions of the world, especially in value added per capita. The latter has stopped declining since 1994 but remains sluggish in a comparative perspective . Area expansion has been the main source of output growth in cereal production in SS-Africa, by contrast to East and South Asia where rising yields were the main source of growth, and to Latin America where area expansion that was initially the main source of growth has also given way to rising yields . However, more than in most other parts of the world, rising land scarcity has become a stark reality for SS-Africa, compromising reliance on area expansion as a future source of growth,rolling benches and calling for emulation of the Latin American growth reversal . Yet, cereal yields have been overall stagnant while those in other regions have increased steadily , with some better performers such as South Africa, Côte d’Ivoire, and Zambia showing the way forward.

Accelerated growth thus requires, and will increasingly require, gains in land productivity that have to this date not materialized at an aggregate level, i.e., a “Green Revolution” for Africa.The food crisis with higher and more volatile international market prices is particularly threatening to SS-Africa where most countries are net food importers and where most of the population spends a high share of its income on food staples.The transmission from international to domestic prices has been highly uneven across countries and commodities, ranging from high transmission for rice in Senegal, Cameroon, and Ghana to low transmission in most other countries, in particular Madagascar, Guinea, Niger, and Malawi, with Uganda an intermediate case . Higher transmission for a particular commodity tends to be associated with greater import dependency and lower diversification in consumption, but the determinants of transmission are also highly idiosyncratic to countries depending on policy interventions,real exchange movements, transactions costs on markets, and the competitive structure in imports and processing. Frequently assumed full transmission has led to overblown predictions of impact. There is a price policy dilemma originating in the contrast between: more stable consumer prices for imported foods with eventual shocks as in the 2007-08 food crisis where there is high transmission as in Senegal, and prices disconnected from the international market for local cereals but with very high and visibly rising variability . The food situation for the world, and especially for SS-Africa, has changed drastically in the last five years. New pressures have emerged both on the demand side associated with continued rapid population growth, income effects, demand for bio-fuels, and on the supply side originating in fluctuating energy prices, climate change, water scarcity, soil depletion, and pandemic zoonotic diseases.

With rising international market prices signaling that supply is overall not keeping up with demand, and rising price volatility in a context of low international grain stocks, defensive trade policies, and speculative movements on commodity markets, much greater focus needs to be placed on the supply side of food, and in particular on achieving sustainable productivity gains and greater resilience to shocks. Dealing with international market price volatility and domestic yield instability raises anew the issue of food security as a major policy concern, when it had slipped off the policy agenda following structural adjustment and trade liberalization. This requires revising policy decisions regarding trade when international market prices for staple foods are more volatile, use of national food reserves, social safety nets for the vulnerable, supply response in agriculture for greater domestic self-sufficiency, and promotion of subsistence farming for “farm-financed social welfare” for those beyond the reach of social safety nets when exposed to shocks. Securing access to food thus requires focusing not only on chronic poverty but also on vulnerability to transitory poverty, with a need to adjust current social assistance programs that are better equipped to deal with the former than with the latter. Assessment of the welfare incidence of price changes needs careful identification of net sellers and net buyers among rural households, most often revealing the surprising fact that a large majority of landed households are in fact net buyers of food, and thus negatively affected by higher and more volatile prices.In spite of greater public concern with agriculture created by the food crisis, the resilience of rural poverty, and the contributions of agriculture to climate change, public budgets allocated to agriculture in Sub-Saharan Africa still fall short of the 10% NEPAD guideline and of the 15% allocated to agriculture by successful Asian countries . Similarly, overseas development assistance allocated to agriculture in SS-Africa remains at historically low levels with only modest improvements after 2006 . There is also continued under-investment in agricultural research when comparing rates of return on investment to the opportunity cost of capital shows that there are high payoffs from such investments. The neglect of agriculture is also apparent in structural adjustment programs that have been highly detrimental to the institutional infrastructure of agriculture, followed by highly incomplete reconstruction of an alternative institutional structure. This includes market facilities, financial services, property rights, producer organizations, and governance for agriculture. An improved performance of agriculture clearly depends on greater attention to the institutions that serve the sector.

While reversing the neglect of agriculture requires increased public expenditures and overseas development assistance to agriculture, the financial crisis is likely to make commitments to agriculture by governments and international donors more difficult to be met. Greater emphasis must consequently be directed at improving the quality of public expenditures and of foreign assistance to agriculture, an area with considerable room for improvement. There are also encouraging new initiatives in progress including the CAADP policy guidelines, a more pro-active role for GFAR, increased budgets for the CGIAR, successful disbursements under the World Bank’s Global Food Crisis Response Program, and the Gates-Rockefeller Foundations’ Agra program. These initiatives need to be supported by high quality monitoring and impact evaluations for guidance and improvement, a support still largely incipient.One of the reasons for poor past performance of public investments in agriculture has been insufficient recognition of the difficulty in doing so. There should be no illusion that successfully using agriculture for development is a complex and multi-pronged enterprise that requires conceptualization, resources, capacity, coordination, political commitment, and time. Short run impacts on poverty are easier and faster to achieve via transfers , explaining the rising popularity of transfers over rising autonomous incomes as instruments, but they cannot be sufficient and adequate to solve the rural poverty problem. Rising autonomous incomes for the rural population has to be the main focus of sustainable poverty reduction strategies. Rainfed agriculture, that accounts for 88% of SS-Africa’s cultivated area, is characterized by a high degree of heterogeneity of conditions . Managing this heterogeneity requires decentralization and participation in order to design and implement local solutions. Heterogeneity also originates in highly varied social systems with a great diversity of institutional arrangements. Multiple constraints require a multi-sectoral approach. Key issues to be addressed include exhausted soils, insufficient infrastructure , low levels of education and health, a private sector limited by an uninviting investment climate, incipient producer organizations, and weak governance for agriculture. Small countries and large economies of scale in such investments as R&D and infrastructure invite regional cooperation. In using agriculture for development, the process through which growth in agriculture is obtained is as important as the outcome, in particular to achieve poverty reduction, gender equality, and environmental sustainability. Smallholder farming must for this reason be the dominant approach in spite of some advantages associated with large scale farming and the contracting out of land to international agribusiness that has recently been advocated by some development economists and pursued by some governments.We see these challenges being successfully addressed in large number of locations. The list of success stories is long and varied . It ranges from land certification schemes that provide security of access and support land rentals, to technological innovations in dealing with drought resistance and improved nutrition, ebb and flow bench more complete financial services that combine credit with savings and insurance, commodity exchanges to improve domestic market performance and create links with international commodity markets, extension systems that more effectively cater to clienteles in using IT capacities, community-driven development schemes with local participation to the delivery of public goods, and producer organizations able to not only serve their membership but acquire voice in the definition of public policy. These success stories need to be better identified, understood, and scaled up so they become reflected in aggregate statistics. Opportunities exist for profitable investments in agriculture, as can be seen in impressive gains achieved in the production of non-traditional exports.

And there is a clear renewal of interest in the private sector for the investment opportunities offered by agriculture. We cannot assume that we know the answers as to how to use agriculture for development in SS-Africa since a productivity revolution has to be idiosyncratic and locally adapted. Useful lessons can be derived from historical successes in other regions and from widespread local achievements in SS-Africa. There is a huge deficit of good social science scholarship applied to issues of agriculture for development in helping identify answers.The Special Feature on Diversified Farming Systems is motivated by a desire to understand how agriculture designed according to whole-systems, agroecological principles can contribute to creating a more sustainable, socially just, and secure global food system. “How to feed the world” is an increasingly urgent and looming concern voiced by many people, from local community groups to national and international governing bodies. By 2050, the world population is projected to rise to 9+ billion and food demands to double from current levels. At the same time, climate change, interacting with increasingly uneven access to declining oil, water, and phosphorus supplies, will greatly exacerbate the year-to-year unpredictability of agricultural production, potentially undermining the entire agricultural enterprise . Meanwhile, industrialized agricultural techniques are exacting a huge toll on surrounding environments, polluting waterways, creating dead zones in the oceans, destroying bio-diverse habitats, releasing toxins into food chains, endangering public health via disease outbreaks and pesticide exposures, and contributing to climate warming . Moreover, industrial agricultural methods are inherently unsustainable in mining soils and aquifers far more quickly than they can be replenished, and in their high use of fossil fuels . These numerous environmental and social externalities create a huge economic cost that industrialized food producers seldom pay. For instance, pesticide use alone causes up to $10 billion in damage to humans and ecosystems in the United States every year . Finally, although the agricultural sector currently produces more than enough calories to feed humanity, one billion people remain hungry and an additional one billion have micro-nutrient deficiencies . This paradoxical situation occurs because many people still lack access to sufficiently diverse and healthy food, or the means to produce it, which is primarily a problem of distribution rather than production . As further evidence of this paradox, global obesity rates have more than doubled since 1980 , reflecting an overproduction of food in industrialized countries that creates strong incentives for agrifood companies to absorb excess food production into processed foods and to market and distribute them to customers in supersized portions . This series of articles examines the proposition that diversified farming systems, with their focus on local production, local and agroecological knowledge, and whole systems approaches reduce negative environmental externalities and decrease social costs associated with industrialized monocultures, enhance the sustainability and resilience of agriculture, and contribute significantly to global food security and health.

Later work emphasized various more flexible technology representations

These models are characterized by a complex set of linear inequality constraints that represent the production possibilities available to a farmer. The simplex optimization algorithm is used to select the optimum production possibilities. One disadvantage of this approach is that the solutions are restricted to extreme points in the multidimensional decision variable space and thus it is unable to explore intermediate solutions. A major problem with linear programming models is that they need complex constraint structures to achieve some degree of calibration to base data; those constraint structures restrict alternative solutions and are difficult to implement for applications such as adoption and impact of new technologies.Econometric methods have been developed and used for single crop production function models as well as single-equation and simultaneous system models that represent input demand and output supply behavior. Early work focused on primal representations and statistical estimation , but many efforts shifted to dual representations in the 1970s and later . Both static and dynamic models have been developed. Single crop production functions are estimated directly from data on the physical quantities of inputs and outputs observed from experimental plots, or, in later stages, from comprehensive farm production surveys. Heady was an early proponent and researcher in this area. In many cases the functional form for the production functions is a quadratic or Cobb Douglas specification, both of which have implicit restrictive assumptions on the production technology. Econometric estimation of agricultural systems was expanded to represent both multi-crop production with its associated interdependencies, the endogenous nature of agricultural supply response, and the imputed value of some key agricultural inputs that are often incompletely priced. A landmark article in this literature noted that multi-crop farm businesses responded to changes in prices or technology by adjusting both the intensity of input use per acre,vertical grow system the intensive margin ; and also the allocation of land to crops, the extensive margin. This distinction is important for modeling optimal input allocation in multi-crop farming systems.

The importance of the interaction of multi-crops in a farm unit was a significant step forward in realistic economic models of farming systems. However, the approach did not include formal linkage to biophysical models of agricultural processes. The econometric approach has limitations in its ability to extrapolate responses that are outside the estimation sample, or those that employ systems that are not present in the data sample. These limitations were emphasized by Antle and Capalbo in their development of economic simulation models that combine econometric and other disciplinary simulation models into an integrated assessment framework.The importance of risk on farm decisions was recognized early in the development of linear optimization models of farming systems. Early articles on this linear approach to risk analysis are by Lin et al. and Hazell and Scandizzo . As improved algorithms to solve quadratic optimization problems were developed, specification of risk expanded to a mean-variance measure of risk and imputed a risk aversion value based on observed farmer actions or primary surveys . Just and Pope introduced a widely-used econometric risk model. Antle introduced a general moment-based representation of output distributions that has been widely used to study production risk behavior, including downside risk. Recent research has extended this approach to investigate impacts of climate change .The importance of space in agricultural production and modeling agricultural systems was first introduced in terms of trade between regions of different comparative advantages. Takayama and Judge showed that spatial equilibrium conditions and transport cost between different production locations could be characterized as a quadratic optimization problem. Spatial econometrics advanced to include rates of development and specialization of production . Only recently has the availability of remotely sensed measures of agricultural land and water use led to the use of spatial econometrics methods to address spatially varying farm production . Techniques are emerging that use both remotely sensed data and spatial econometrics to draw conclusions about resource use or the effect of spatial variation on agricultural supply response.Complex simulation models have been used for the past 45 years to describe dynamic agricultural systems.

Early examples were often based on Forrester’s concept of system dynamics that uses storage and flow variables to describe the system. However the underlying philosophy that a comprehensive and complex feedback system is stable and reproducible has never been convincingly demonstrated. Structural simulation models can be useful for representing a combination of consistent behavioral relationships based on theory and empirical measurement. They are however, subject to interpretation in the absence of robustly estimated relationships describing system behavior. Various micro-economic models have been developed to simulate the economic behavior of agricultural systems and link behavior to environmental processes and economic sustainability indicators. van Wijk et al. document the large number and diversity of such models, that include: applications of various types of linear or non-linear programming models; household models ; agent-based models that incorporate spatial and temporal interactions among households; and models that link economic models with bio-physical crop, livestock, and environmental models. Recently, agent-based modeling has been widely used as a way of modeling interactive human behavior and natural systems. Some agent-based models have a more formal dynamic and calibration structure and use mixed-integer optimization approaches for solutions. However, the generality of the approach makes it susceptible to the same difficulties of empirical verification and reproducibility that earlier complex structural simulation models had. The population-based modeling approach of Antle et al. is a more parsimonious, generic approach designed to represent agricultural system heterogeneity. It links economic simulation models to bio-physical models to evaluate impacts of technology, policy and environmental changes on sustainability.Along with more complex constrained models, researchers have developed optimization models that utilize shadow values of resources and calibration constraints to derive nonlinear calibrating functions, which are termed positive mathematical programming . In the past 10 years PMP has developed from formal calibration methods that reproduce the observed cropping pattern to those that calibrate crop supplies to prior estimates of supply elasticities , and more complex production functions that calibrate against elasticities of substitution and returns to scale. In addition, PMP models are now being formally linked with biophysical models .

These macroeconomic models spawned a series of smaller-scale models which are usually called village or household models. General equilibrium village models account for all flows in the village economy and remittances within the village to different workers and landowners. In addition, they include flows of revenue in and out of the village boundary. This is particularly useful in developing country farm economies where much of the labor is supplied by family members with little or no pay. Another advantage of village-level equilibrium models is that they account for the utility gained from subsistence food grown in a village. These CGE models are anchored by a social accounting matrix that accounts for flows within and outside the economy. Moreover, it is common practice to fit the standard functional form such as a constant elasticity of substitution production, supply, or transformation function that is calibrated against exogenously estimated elasticities . CGE models have the disadvantage of being data and computationally intensive due to their more general specification, and for the quite restrictive assumptions required for their solution. Compared with more detailed partial equilibrium models, general equilibrium models are harder to incorporate detailed process models.Flichman describes recent studies on application of models that combine bio-physical and economic models to represent agricultural systems. Flichman and Allen and van Wijk et al. also survey economic agricultural system models. They characterize bio-economic models into farm, landscape, regional, and national models. Systems in each of these scales include crops, livestock, and socioeconomics components that interact in complex ways. For example, Fig. 5 shows components that need to be included in system models at the farm scale. These components and processes encompass the crop and livestock production enterprises of a farm, the household decision and production processes, and the interactions among the household and production systems of the farm. Within these scales the cited authors address both static and dynamic specifications. In his introduction Flichman attributes growth of bio-economic modeling to two developments: improvement of biophysical agricultural simulation models, and evolution of agricultural policies that demand integrated assessments that conventional economic models cannot provide. We briefly address three prominent areas of application of integrated bio-economic models.An alternative econometric approach to measuring the impact of climate change both on agricultural crop yields and on economic variables such as land values and economic returns is to estimate statistical models based on observed behavior. These statistical models are then simulated with data from future climate projections. A justification for this approach is that it can embed realistic adaptive behavior into the model . However, this type of model also has significant weaknesses. For example, it does not incorporate effects of CO2 fertilization on crop productivity,mobile grow system cannot represent changes in socio-economic conditions, and cannot be used to identify technological adaptations distinct from climate impacts. Various researchers have used statistical econometric methods to model the effects of climate on yields and other variables .Havlik et al. provides an overview of integrated livestock modeling and its use in mitigating climate change. Their analysis is driven by a large-scale economic optimization model that assesses crop bio-energy production, land-use changes, water requirements, and greenhouse gas emissions. Their results show that improvements in livestock production systems can significantly reduce impacts on fragile land use and improve the effectiveness of climate mitigation policies. In another approach, Kobayashi et al. analyzed stocking density impacts on Kazakhstan’s extensive rangelands using a stochastic dynamic programming model for multiple livestock systems with stochastic forage production. They showed that cost of capital strongly affects herd size and productivity.There is a rich history of modeling watershed and environmental quality, however much of this has not incorporated goals related to agricultural systems and only a few efforts incorporate crop and livestock models. There are at least two different perspectives about modeling across space, including the interconnectedness of agricultural and ecological systems across the landscape. The first perspective is that human systems, including the farm, communities, and administrative and political areas in which agricultural systems interact through decisions and policies, affect production systems, markets, and trade.

The other perspective is that the interconnectedness among hydrological and biophysical processes establishes the underlying behavior of agricultural systems over the landscape. This perspective leads to an emphasis on understanding physical, chemical, and biological processes that occur in watersheds. Both perspectives are important, yet agricultural models rarely consider both in the same assessments or models. There are many applications of watershed hydrology models, in particular using the SWAT model as discussed byGassman et al. , mainly focusing on environmental quality and water resource issues. Fig. 6 shows the regional integrated assessment approach developed by AgMIP that emphasizes linkages of agricultural systems across space using the first perspective noted above . In this perspective, based in part on the impact assessment approach developed by Antle , the focus is on the economic, environmental, and social impacts of alternative systems within heterogeneous household populations. However, this framework also illustrates the feed backs from farms to agro-ecological regions to national and global scales. We often use the term “scaling up” of model results to refer to the aggregation of model results from finer spatial resolutions to a larger area. If the areas of interest are defined by hydrologists, they tend to be watersheds. In contrast, if the areas are defined by economists, they tend to be administrative and political units or socio-economic stratifications . These perspectives are not mutually exclusive, however. In fact, they lend themselves to include both human and biophysical/hydrological processes. A challenge for next generation agricultural models is to include the technical aspects of integrated modeling and a transdisciplinary approach in which scientists recognize the need for collaboration, not only on specific projects, but also in designing models and decision support tools to achieve their goals. Many current agricultural system models have been developed to evaluate practices and policies associated with environmental quality. Biophysical models typically operate at the point/field scales with an emphasis on vertical fluxes of energy, water, C, N and nutrients throughout the atmosphere, plant, and soil root-zone continuum. Upscaling from point to the landscape scale requires estimation of surface and subsurface fluxes and ecological transitions along the lateral scale.

This trend is caused by the drought years of the hydrologic period used for future projections

Food production, defined as the total yield of crops measured in tons, started at 3.4 million tons in 2000 for both scenarios, decreased to 1.9 million tons in 2009, and then increased to 2.9 million tons in 2015. For the future projections, from 2016 to 2020, the optimized scenario delivered more food than the baseline given the available land, but the baseline scenario showed steadily higher amounts of food production from 2022 to 2040 due to the fixed acreages and available water in that scenario. Food production decreased 8.5% under the optimization scenario.Groundwater has been over drafted in Pajaro Valley for decades . The modeling results from this study illustrate aquifer depletion, where 49 years of historical annual time series of inflows and outflows are estimated through a GBM and compared to PVHM . GBM results show an estimated annual average overdraft of −14.8 million m3=year from 1966 to 2009, close to the PVHM result of −15.9 million m3=year. Comparing the simulation models of GBM and PVHM has its limitations. GBM does not include certain inflows [landward underflow and stream flow infiltration, subtotal 17,930 thousands acre-ft ð TAFÞ=year on average] and outflows [storage flow depletion, storage depletion masked by seawater intrusion, outflows to the bay and tile drains, subtotal 18,910 TAF=year on average], which approximately cancel each other out. While these components contribute to the hydrology of the basin, GBM omits these components for simplification, and it represents a limitation of the model. The GBM was evaluated from 2016 to 2040 under two scenarios to estimate the average net groundwater storage of the area . Both scenarios began with an overall depletion of −57 million m3=year in 2015. This significant depletion of groundwater is related to the most recent multiyear drought in California that began in 2012,ebb flow tray which exacerbated the exploitation of groundwater resources because of the lack of groundwater regulations and policies in California before the passage of SGMA.

Both projections display similar behavior; however, the optimized scenario shows overall less groundwater depletion for the Pajaro Valley groundwater basin. The optimized scenario projects 10 years where the aquifer storage is zero or positive from 2020 to 2033. Both projections show the greatest depletion in 2040, with aquifer storage levels of −83 million m3=year and −48 million m3=year for the baseline and optimized scenarios, respectively.The highest storage point is 2 million m3 in 2033 and 35 million m3 in 2023 on the baseline and optimization scenarios, respectively. Overall, the GBM projections from 2016 to 2040 showed an average net groundwater depletion of −48 million m3=year for the baseline scenario in contrast with −10 million m3=year for the optimized scenario. This illustrates the possibility of a 79% increase in net groundwater storage from 2016 to 2040. Focusing on a shorter period from 2016 to 2030, the difference between projections is even greater with −47 million m3=year for the baseline scenario and −5 million m3=year for the optimization scenario, which is an 89% increase in net groundwater storage from 2016 to 2030. A single factor ANOVA evaluation indicated a significant difference in the net groundwater storage between scenarios. These findings support part of the study goal, which was that constraining agricultural water use can result in less groundwater overdraft. These results illustrate that groundwater simulation models can estimate future trends in groundwater depletion, consistent with previous studies in other agricultural and groundwater-dependent areas of California, while also validating the innovate application of optimization models to explore ecological and sustainable solutions to groundwater and land management challenges .

There are opportunities to improve water management in Pajaro Valley to reduce aquifer depletion and prioritize a reliable supply of freshwater for population demands and agriculture activities if farmers are incentivized to making collective decisions to optimize profits while managing groundwater sustainably.Successful productivity growth in agriculture has been the source of early development and subsequent structural transformation and industrialization in most of today’s high income countries. This has been amply documented by the work of historians such as Bairoch who analyzed at the Western industrialization experience, cascading from England in the mid- 1700s, to France and Germany around 1820, the United States and Russia in the mid-1800s, and finally Japan with restauration of the Meiji emperors in 1880. Following WWII, agriculture has similarly been the engine of growth and transformation for the Asian industrialization miracles in Taiwan, South Korea, China , and Vietnam . In all these countries, an agricultural revolution preceded a subsequent industrial take-off, typically by something like a half century. Agriculture has also fulfilled an important role in facilitating industrialization in countries like India, Brazil, and Chile . Agriculture remains today the expected engine of growth for the “agriculture-based countries”, those countries with a high contribution of agriculture to GDP growth and a high share of their poor in the rural sector . These are also countries where the farm population is importantly composed of smallholder farmers , in some cases exclusively and in others coexisting with larger commercial farms . In both cases, agricultural growth importantly requires modernization of the operation of SHFs. With labor-intensive industrialization increasingly compromised by robotization and the reshoring of industries toward the industrialized countries , agriculture with agroindustry and the associated linkages to services and non-tradable consumption has been heralded as a potentially effective strategy for GDP growth in these countries . This includes most of the Sub-Saharan Africa countries. This approach is a major departure from the classical structural transformation approach based on labor-intensive industrialization advocated in the dual economy models . The World Development Report Agriculture for Development’s main message was that agriculture-based countries should invest more in agriculture in order to fully capture its potential for growth and poverty reduction.

Following the world food crisis of 2008, there was a short-term positive response by governments, international organizations, and the donor community with a sharp increase in investment in agriculture. The number of countries meeting the CAADEP goal of allocating at least 10% of government expenditures to agriculture increased from 3 in 2007 to 10 in 2009. Overseas development assistance to agriculture increased by 60% between 2007 and 2009. But this response has not been sustained. In 2014 only 2 SSA countries out of 43 met the CAADEP goal. The modal SSA country spends only 5% of its public expenditures on agriculture. No SSA country spends a percentage of its public budget on agriculture that reaches the percentage contribution of agriculture to GDP, and 75% of the countries spend less than half that percentage . CAADEP also set a goal for public spending on agricultural Research-and-Development to reach 1% of agricultural GDP. Returns to investing in agricultural research are typically significantly in excess of cost relative to other public programs, indicating under-investment . This takes extreme forms in SSA where investment is by far the lowest among regions and has been declining over the last decade. In 2011, only six countries met the CAADEP research goal . With failure to invest in agriculture, the yield gap on cereals has continued to increase between SSA and other regions of the world. This gap is correlated with a growing chemical fertilizer gap and a large deficit in irrigation. Today, the World Development Report’s main message continues to be advocated by international development organizations such as the World Bank, the Food and Agriculture Organization, and the International Fund for Agricultural Development . This is motivated by the observation that 51% of the world extreme poor live in SSA, a share that continues to rise, and 78% of the world extreme poor work in agriculture in spite of rapid urbanization. Success in using Agriculture for Development is thus essential to meet the Sustainable Development Goals on poverty and hunger. In the current global economic context for the SSA countries,flood and drain tray investing in agriculture where the poor work has proven more effective for poverty reduction than taking the poor out of agriculture and to an urban-industrial environment through a Lewis -type structural transformation. Research shows that the poor are not found in agriculture due to adverse selection. Poverty reduction, where it has happened, has been more effective through productivity growth where the poor work than through structural transformation . A Solow-type decomposition of sources of growth shows that agricultural output growth in SSA in the 1985- 2012 period originated for 63% from area expansion compared to 8% from factor deepening and 29% from productivity growth . This is not sustainable due to an effective land constraint and declining farm size in most countries as a consequence of rapid population growth. Take Malawi as an example where agricultural land for households engaged in agricultural production fell from 2.3 acres in 2004, to 1.8 in 2010, and 1.4 in 2016 . Productivity growth and factor deepening consequently have to be the main sources of growth in SSA agriculture as in the rest of the developing world where they account for 83% of agricultural output growth.

This opinion on the role of agriculture for development is far from universally shared in the development community. Gollin et al. and Collier and Dercon have argued that rural poverty reduction has to come from employment creation in the urban-industrial environment and a structural transformation of the economy. As seen above, governments have correspondingly not invested public resources in agriculture to the recommended levels. Hence the puzzle in using agriculture for development is: why has the World Development Report/CAADEP recommendation not been followed? We argue here that it is because the mainly supply-side approach used for implementation has proved insufficiently effective, and needs to be complemented for this by a more explicit demand-side approach. There are African countries to look at for successful progress toward productivity growth in staple foods and a rural transformation . Chemical fertilizer use is overall low , but uneven across countries. The LSMS-ISA data show that the share of cultivating households using chemical fertilizer reaches 77% in Malawi, 56% in Ethiopia, and 41% in Nigeria, while remaining at 17% in Niger and Tanzania, and 3% in Uganda . Rural transformation is accompanied by land concentration in medium farms in countries like Kenya , Ghana , Tanzania , and Zambia . These farms are typically mechanized and owned by well-educated urban-based professionals who can be effective agents for technology adoption. These various success stories show that using agriculture for development can be done, but has not yet been sufficient to overcome aggregate rising gaps in yields between SSA and the rest of the world.While there has been limited success with raising public expenditures on agriculture, there has been considerable progress with data collection and with rigorous experimentation on how to promote the modernization of agriculture. We consequently know a lot more today about how to use agriculture for development than we did ten years ago, even though this knowledge has most often not been put into practice in the desirable form and to the desirable degree. It is consequently important to start by reviewing what we have learned. The main argument that has been used in support of the need for a structural transformation as the mechanism to grow and reduce poverty is that there is a large labor productivity gap between agriculture and non-agriculture . An important observation, however, based on the LSMS-ISA data for SSA is that while the gap in labor productivity per person per year between non-agriculture and agriculture is indeed large, the gap in labor productivity per hour worked is relatively small . In other words, when agricultural workers do work, their labor productivity is not very different from that of non-agricultural workers. What this suggests is that there is a deficit in work opportunities for agricultural vs. non-agricultural workers that creates an income gap between the two categories of workers. Because households engage in a multiplicity of sectoral activities, the relevant contrast in labor productivity is not between agriculture and non-agriculture, but between rural and urban households, with rural households typically principally engaged in agriculture. Looking at labor calendars for rural and urban households in Malawi in Figure 1, we see that weekly household hours worked are not different for rural and urban households at peak labor time, which corresponds to the planting season in December and January .

Recent initiatives in grain market reform also appear to be particularly encouraging

Despite the gains in market performance in recent years, WTO makes demands on China’s domestic agricultural markets. Domestic marketing policy response to the nation’s impending WTO accession has been substantial and will continue. Major changes are aimed at improving the efficiency of domestic market performance and minimizing the adverse shocks that may arise from external trade liberalization. Perhaps more than in any other sector, the reforms in cotton and grain markets that China agreed to in the final stages of China’s WTO negotiation clearly show that its leaders are using this opportunity to develop its health domestic agricultural market. The case of cotton presents a good example. In 1999, officials began experimenting in the North China Plain with marketing reforms for cotton, frequently considered the second most important strategic agricultural commodity . The reforms were aimed at improving cotton market performance by reducing market transaction costs, creating a market-oriented pricing mechanism, and integrating regional markets. The main policy measure sought to eliminate the current monopolized state-own cotton procurement and distribution system. In part reflecting the fact that informal markets had already been working for many years, the disruption to cotton markets after liberalization were almost non-existent. With a successful performance of this experimental reform, the liberalization policy was expanded substantially in 2000 and fully implemented in 2001. Domestically, over the past two decades state-owned grain traders have chronically performed poorly due to imperfect incentives and a number of taxing policy burdens. Although many companies have received considerable marketing subsidies,ebb flow bench the losses of these firms have always been a burden on the national leaders.

Moreover, although it had appeared reformers had solved this problem in the mid-1990s, retrenchments in agricultural policy created a situation in which many state-owned grain companies were still losing money in the late 1990s. Internationally, there were also concerns over several commonly executed policies that are now being addressed. For example, WTO negotiators expressed their opinion that China’s traditional ways of pricing agriculture were distorting. Others believe that the rights of state owned grain trading enterprises to procure commodities from farmers under special access rights give certain domestic firms unfair access and violates national treatment principles of WTO. Facing these pressures and concerns, China has launched a new set of reforms in the area of state grain marketing system in 2000. Building on past efforts to liberalize markets and continuing with the tradition of moving gradually, many believe that the measures included in this round are ultimately expected to have a defining influence on China’s grain markets in the years to come. As part of the first step, the restrictions on grain procurement for lower quality grains such as the early indica rice and maize in southern China, spring wheat in northern China, and all wheat in southern China were phased out in 2000. After the policy was set in place, any trader was allowed to buy or sell grain from any farmer or other trader at any time. Almost immediately this policy resulted in an adjustment in the structure of the cropping patterns in some regions. In the last several years, producers have begun planting varieties to improve grain quality. Many of these improvement will mean that to some extent China’s farmers are in a more competitive position to produce and sell varieties that might otherwise come in from foreign sources, for example, high quality rice from Thailand or high quality wheat from Canada or the US. With successful performance of grain “varietal” reform in 2000, leaders are now going to officially liberalize grain markets. Depending on the deregulation of all grain-related procurement and sales, leaders are first implementing their policies in a subset of grain-deficit, coastal provinces, Zhejiang, Jiangsu, Shanghai, Fujian, Guangdong, and Hainan. Currently, the government is planning to extend the implementation of the policies in all grain deficit provinces in 2002.

As seen in the past, given such close ties between traders in surplus and deficit areas, such policies in deficit areas will almost certainly naturally envelope all of China. In response to WTO accession, the government also have ambitious plans to increase investment in market infrastructure. Leaders see a need to establish an effective national marketing information network. Officials in the ministry of agriculture are attempting to standardize agricultural product quality and promote farm marketing. Some also have advocated the creation of agricultural technology associations. More generally, all of these moves are part of an effort by leaders to shift fiscal resources that used to be used to support China’s expensive price subsidization schemes to productivity-enhancing investments and marketing infrastructure improvements. The magnitude of this policy response is highlighted by the fact that the total subsidies for price and market interventions reached 40.3 billion in 2000, about 4 percent of national fiscal budget, more than any components of government expenditure in agricultural and rural area of bureaucrats that manage China’s agricultural policies, 93 billion on integrated agricultural development program, and 12.3 billion on poverty alleviation–CNSB, 2001. While not all of these funds were being used on distorting policies or non-productive administration, much of it was. If a good part of the funds is able to be redirected into more productive areas, there is a chance that the agricultural sector can be energized by this new windfall. The policy implications of China’s WTO accession on land use and farm organization also are hotly debated. Many of the concerns have arisen over the ability of China’s small farms to be able to compete after trade liberalization. Although every farm household in China is endowed with land, the average farm size is small, and declining . Leaders are pleased with the equity effects of the nation’s distribution of land as it allays concerns about food security and poverty. Land fragmentation and the extremely small scale of farms, however, almost certainly will in some way constrain the growth of labor productivity on the farm and hold back farm income.

The debate has centered on these issues: Some argue that farm size could be expanded and agricultural productivity could rise if policy makers were to advocate more secure land tenure arrangements. Others call for a continuation of policies that allow localities to periodically re-allocated land to the farmers in order to keep land in the hands of all rural residents. Although most policy makers currently seem to favor more secure rights, they still are searching for complementary measures that will not forego all of the pro-equity benefits of the current land management regime. Land ownership in rural areas, by law, is collectively owned by the village or small group and contracted to households . One of the most important changes in recent years has been that the duration of the use contract was extended from 15 to 30 years. By 2000, about 98% of villages had amended their contract with farmers to reflect the longer set of use rights . Although some were concerned that household and village demographics and other policy pressures often induce local authorities to reallocate land prior to contract expiration, it has been shown that the area of this reallocated land has been minimal and the effect on investment behavior insignificant . With the issue of use rights, resolved, the government is now searching for a mechanism that permits the remaining full-time farmers to gain access additional cultivated land and increase their income and competitiveness. One of the main efforts revolves around the development of a new Rural Land Contract Law. The Standing Committee of the National People’s Congress has drafted a law and the main body is expected to approve it in the near future. According to this law, although the property rights over the ownership of the land remains with the collective, the Law conveys almost all other rights to the contract holder that they would have under a private property system. In particular, the Law clarifies the rights for transfer and exchange of the contracted land, an element that may already be taking effect as researchers are finding increasing more land in China is rented in and out . The new legislation also allows farmers to use contracted land for collateral to secure commercial loan. Part of the law also allows family members to inherit the land during the contracted period. The goal of this new set of policies is to encourage farmers to use their land to increase their farms and household short and long-run productivity. Although quite controversial,4x8ft rolling benches the effort to increase China’s agricultural productivity under trade liberalization also is made through the promotion of large farm enterprises. Many officials in the MOA consider this effort as one of important forces that may help to restructuring China’s agriculture, expand agricultural markets, and increase farmer income. Recently fiscal authorities have supported this effort by making grants and allowing tax reductions for the infrastructure investments of the farms. They also have provided large farms with credit subsidies for input procurement and the financing of their efforts to update their technology at all levels of the food change . As a result of China’s WTO accession, the support in this area is expected to increase. However, more effort in the future is likely to shift to supplying services that are supposed to be provided by government in areas such as farm infrastructure development, technology adoption, and extension, rather than direct intervention and subsidy. As subsidies through agricultural investment and inputs in China are subject to WTO restrictions on Aggregate Market Support , it is not expected that the extent of these subsidies will restrict such support. China will be limited to its support of large farms to levels that do not exceed its de minimis level of AMS of 8.5%.

However, it is much more likely that its ability to finance agricultural subsidies will be more binding than the WTO-imposed rules. The other major attempt to increase farm productivity and agricultural competitiveness under trade liberalization is to promote the development of farmer organizations. The government has now officially cast its support for self-organized farmer groups that focus agricultural technology and marketing . At one time, the creation of farmer organization was a political sensitive issue. Leaders were concerned with the rise of any organization outside the government’s authority. Such restrictions, however, caused a dilemma in reforming the nation’s agricultural and rural economies. Policy makers also are aware that with the small scale of China’s farms there are many increases in economic efficiency that might be gained by the creation of effective rural organizations and that if they were successful in raising incomes, there might be a rise in political stability.It is on this basis, then, that leaders have now decided to allow the organization of China’s 240 million farms. Letting these millions of small farmers competing in a market with globalization requires substantial institutional reforms on farm organization and provisions of government service such as technology extension and marketing information and quality controls. It will be in these areas that farmer organizations will be encouraged. In addition, these types of farm organizations that are supported by the government fall under WTO’s “Green Box” categorization and investments to create such groups will not be counted as part of the nation’s AMS measures. Perhaps more than anything, the government is going to need these farmer organizations to lead the fight against the imposition of trade barriers on China’s agricultural exports. Because China’s producers have not been organized, when foreign countries, such as Japan, Korea, and the US have levied trade barriers, typically citing dumping. Even when such cases were based on questionable bases, China had no one who had an incentive or ability to contest the cases. Since China Provisions of anti-dumping and safeguards measures against China’s products, such cases will not abate and the nation needs to have a way to protect the interest of those seeking to export.The financial sector has reformed more slowly than some other sector, and government maintains strong control . Among the commitments regarding the banking sector, the Protocol requires China to open the country’s financial markets in a step by step way. The liberalization must allow foreign competition across wider and wider regions and customer base. After a four years transition period, all regional restrictions will be removed and foreign banks will receive national non-discriminative treatment in the area of banking services. Specifically, restrictions on branch banking can not be imposed.

Each block has an agricultural office that is led by a Block Agricultural Officer

None of these studies consider whether engaging the supply side of the market can increase adoption by farmers. Survey data in agriculture suggest that input suppliers act as the second most popular source of information for Indian farmers. Informing private input suppliers about technological benefits is one way to take advantage of their intrinsic motivation to spread information. Yet, it has not been looked at as source of potential information agents with well-aligned incentives in promoting the adoption of new technologies. Our paper is the first to implement and test this as a new approach to doing agricultural extension.The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 gives more background information on the setting and outlines the experiment. Section 3 describes the data collection. Section 4 presents the main results on how targeting agricultural extension to input dealers increases technology adoption by farmers, particularly those with the highest potential benefit. Section 5 turns to analyzing a potential explanation for this result. Particularly, it focuses on whether dealers spread information to their customers and what motivates them to do so. Section 6 concludes. This section starts by providing background information on the standard methods used in agricultural extension. It also gives a description of how the public sector delivers information to farmers in our particular study area. We then outline the design of our main experiment to compare these standard methods with the more business-oriented approach of using agrodealers as information agents. Governments all over the world support agricultural extension services as a mode of information delivery. Ministries of agriculture typically have entire departments dedicated to providing these services. These departments oversee local administrative offices that hire front line extension agents whose role is to diffuse information about new agricultural technologies and practices to farmers.

The specific techniques used by agents vary across contexts, but the basic methods are largely consistent,indoor garden especially in poor countries. Agents usually work with selected “contact farmers” who are keen on trying new approaches and are ideally able to transmit knowledge to others in their social networks. They also organize farmer field days with cluster demonstration plots, where new seeds are grown by multiple farmers, to boost the diffusion of information. The public sector provides agricultural extension services for at least two reasons. First, markets do not exist for many new innovations. For instance, a new planting method may only be promoted by government agents because there is no scope for profiting from its sale in private markets. This contrasts with new seed varieties or material inputs that are produced and sometimes marketed by private firms. Second, many agricultural innovations are not developed, and hence not marketed, by private firms. Public entities such as national agricultural research systems or international research organizations frequently develop new seeds, inputs, and agricultural management practices. The public extension service then transmits information about these developments to farmers. In the context of our experiment, agricultural extension workers use many of these standard techniques. Each of the 10 districts in the sample is organized into blocks, where a block has an average of 135 villages.The BAO employs Assistant Agricultural Officers and Village Agricultural Workers who work in the field with farmers. Our sample consists of 72 blocks in 10 flood-prone districts of Odisha.We selected these areas because the technology being promoted — a flood-tolerant rice variety called Swarna-Sub1 — is most suitable for flood-affected areas.

The blocks in the sample represent around 20 percent of the blocks in the state. We randomly assigned 36 of these blocks to the treatment group where agrodealers were targeted to receive seeds and information. This randomization was stratified by district. The remaining 36 blocks serve as a comparison group where we supported the government extension service to carry out normal extension activities. Figure 1 displays the timeline of these interventions. Starting in May 2016 — about 6-8 weeks before planting time — we partnered with the government’s extension service to introduce Swarna-Sub1 into control blocks. We did this in a way that mirrors three common practices in agricultural extension. First, field staff provided 10 seed minikits of 5 kilograms each to the BAO, who then helped identify contact farmers to use the kits. The BAO chose 2 villages and 5 farmers in each village. Each kit contained only seeds for testing and some basic information about Swarna-Sub1. Our field staff then delivered the kits to the recommended farmers. Second, we provided another 150 kg of seeds to the BAO so that he could set up a cluster demonstration where the seeds would be used by several farmers on a contiguous set of plots. Based on seeding rates in the region, 150 kg allows for cultivation of 5-10 acres. The BAO chose where to do the demonstration and which farmers to target. Official government guidelines for organizing these clusters suggest that they be carried out in sites that are easily accessible to be viewed by many farmers. Moreover, sites should be representative of average conditions in the area. Third, we helped the BAO carry out a farmer field day in November — at the time right before harvest. The BAO selected the location of the field day and whom to invite. The purpose of the field day was for extension staff to train farmers about Swarna-Sub1, share information from the demonstrations, and hope that information will spread throughout the block. The objective of such an active control group is twofold. First, it ensures that each block is endowed with the same quantity of seeds. Therefore, the dealer-based treatment only differs on who received the new seeds and information. Second, the demonstrations and partnerships with contact farmers may not have taken place without our involvement. Forcing these activities to happen makes the treatment-control comparison more meaningful. Most importantly, it sets a higher bar for the dealer-based treatment by eliminating any possibility that the new technology would not be promoted by the government extension service.

Turning to the 36 treatment blocks, we obtained a list of 2,087 seed suppliers from the state Department of Agriculture. These include suppliers of two types: private seed dealers and Primary Agricultural Cooperative Societies . PACS are farmer groups that handle credit, seed supply, and procurement of output for farmers. We did not include them in the intervention because their incentives are not the same as those of private dealers. Seed sales are usually handled by a member that is not the residual claimant on any profits from the sale. Despite being fewer in number relative to PACS, private dealers account for almost 60 percent of the seeds sold to farmers. The sample consists of 666 private dealers, 327 of which were located in the treatment blocks. Armed with this list, our field staff entered each treatment block and located five dealers interested in receiving seed minikits and an informational pamphlet about SwarnaSub1. In some blocks fewer than 5 dealers were available. We provided additional seed to each dealer in these cases to guarantee that a full 200 kilograms were introduced. The list provided by the Department of Agriculture did not have enough locatable dealers in some cases. In these circumstances, our field staff provided the seeds to other local agrodealers.Overall, seeds and information were provided to 151 dealers across the 36 treatment blocks.119 of these were from the original list. Once provided with seeds and information, the dealers were left alone to decide how to use them. We asked dealers about their intended uses. They overwhelmingly stated that they would use the seeds for testing on their own farms and would provide them to good customers for testing.Our intervention did not include any additional assistance to dealers. This differs from standard methods in agricultural extension where agents continually revisit their contact farmers. We allowed dealers to learn on their own because in theory they should be motivated to learn about a new product that could enhance their business. The goal of our treatment is to measure whether this motivation causes information to flow to farmers and ultimately increases adoption. Not intervening further ensures that our treatment effect is driven by any real-world incentives dealers have to learn, rather than heavy monitoring by our partners. Dealers in our sample are small business entrepreneurs. Some operate out of their homes, while others maintain shops in rural towns. 44 percent of dealers sell only seeds,hydroponic farming with fertilizers and pesticides being the most common inputs sold by the other dealers. Dealers are highly local. The median dealer sells enough rice seed to cover roughly 400 acres, which amounts to the rice area cultivated by 150 farmers.Importantly, dealers tend to serve the same customers from year to year. Another important feature of our context is that 84% of the seeds sold by dealers in our sample are produced by the state-run Odisha State Seed Corporation . Government subsidies explain this. Seeds produced by the state are subsidized at a rate of approximately 40 percent. No subsidies exist for seeds produced by private companies. As licensed agents, dealers receive a fixed commission that amounts to about 8 percent of the pre-subsidy price. All varieties have the same final price for farmers. Thus, the margin for dealers is the same across all types of varieties. Hence dealers have no direct financial incentive to sell one variety over another. Turning to the second season , we ran an SMS messaging experiment to compare our intervention with this “lighter touch” information treatment.

The random delivery of SMS messages allows us to test whether our dealer treatment substitutes basic knowledge that can be easily transmitted via ICT technology. Furthermore, it allows us to compare the direct effects of the two approaches. The messaging was simple. It informed farmers that Swarna-Sub1 is a new variety that is suitable for medium-low land in terms of elevation, matures in 145 days, and can tolerate up to two weeks of flooding. The message also stated that it was being produced by OSSC and could be available at local dealers. As a sampling frame, we obtained mobile numbers for 75,616 farmers that had registered for the state government’s Direct Benefit Transfer scheme to obtain seed subsidies.These farmers are located across the 261 gram panchayats that cover our main estimation sample, as outlined below. The SMS treatment was randomized at the gram panchayat level, resulting in messages being delivered to 37,783 of the names on the list.We anticipated that dealers and contact farmers would use the demonstration minikits for learning in 2016 and any possible treatment effects could first be detected during year two . Our main followup survey therefore took place in August-September 2017 — around 15 months after the interventions. Its purpose was to measure adoption of seed varieties by rice farmers. To minimize measurement error, we timed the survey to be right after planting. Our sample consists of 7,200 farmers. These farmers were drawn from a random sample of 261 gram panchayats — an administrative unit usually consisting of around 8 villages.Before drawing this sample, we excluded gram panchayats that had any village within 1.5 kilometers of the block boundary.We removed these areas to reduce any interference caused by farmers possibly obtaining seeds from other blocks. The 261 sample gram panchayats had 75,616 farmers registered for the DBT program for seed subsidies. Using this database as a sampling frame, we randomly drew 100 farmers from each block . These farmers are spread across 1,333 villages. Figure A1 shows their geographic dispersion across the 10 districts in the experiment. Survey teams succeeded in locating and surveying 6,653 of the farmers. Of these, 93 percent were currently cultivating rice. Table A1 shows no significant differences in the probabilities of being surveyed or growing rice between treatment and control groups. The survey focused on which seed varieties were currently being used for rice cultivation. Surveyors went through a list of 30 varieties and asked farmers which ones they were currently using and the amount of land being grown.In addition to these adoption data, we obtained information on contacts with agricultural extension agents during the last year, topics discussed during these conversations, whether the farmer had seen any seed demonstrations, and whether they had recently learned about Swarna-Sub1.

Relations between the indigenous and refugee varied from friendly to outright hostile

Those with no money whatsoever were given an allowance and low interest loans subsidized by SOPRO, and housing that the society had leased provided the refugees with much needed shelter. Society funds also paid for the establishment of a twenty-bed hospital and a small home and kindergarten for the children in the capital city. To the southeast of the capital, in the city of Cochabamba, elevation 8,500 feet, SORPRO established a home for the elderly and a sanatorium for those seeking relief from the extreme altitude of the capital.Agricultural training centers were set up to teach refugees the rudiments of farming in a semitropical and tropical environment. Many had no notion of what it meant to work the land; their ranks were filled with professionals such as chemists, engineers, lawyers and physicians. Indeed, in a letter to Hochschild, the Joint’s Paul Baerwald emphasized the importance of success, yet Baerwald also had his deep-seated doubts. “Jewish farm settlement is a much more difficult problem than settlement of peasants.” The Jewish refugee needed both acclimatization and ‘psycho-physiological retraining and readjustment’ Baerwald emphasized. Indeed, besides acclimatizing, one also had to acculturate to a largely indigenous populace, people whose customs and food were exotic in the extreme.There existed elements of the Bolivian population who viewed the newcomers as trespassers who took work from the native, that the displaced refugee was creating the displaced native. Yet there were those who also proffered the hand of friendship in the dynamic relationship between foreigner and native. However, cordial relationships between the refugee and the native could not make up for the shortcomings of the settlement plan. The scholar León E. Bieber lists the factors that led to the abandonment of Buena Tierra,plant benches and notes that a combination of reasons was responsible for its ultimate failure. Among them were the “negligencia en la selección de los inmigrantes.” Many ofthe refugees were professionals, and during the interview process had lied about their backgrounds and level of experience as farmers.

The pressure to escape the Nazis and save one’s life was just too much; hence there were physicians, engineers and other professionals who had falsely claimed an agricultural background. Other key reasons that Bieber noted were the “factores topográficos, la calidad de las tierras, la precaria estructura vial boliviana y la falta de adecuado apoyo.” The sheer isolation of Buena Tierra and the Yungas was due to a paucity of roads and railroad lines into the region. Had this transportation network infrastructure been in place, Buena Tierra may have prospered.The quality of the land and soil at Buena Tierra was hyped by the agronomist Bonoli, who, it turned out, “was profoundly mistaken.”Bieber cited the lack of sufficient government help as another factor that contributed to Buena Tierra’s demise. To achieve success it was essential to have, besides aid from Jewish philanthropies, the full support of the Bolivian Government. Finally, most of the refugees viewed Buena Tierra, and the host country Bolivia, as a stepping stone to other, more enticing locales such as the United States or Argentina, two American countries with thriving Jewish communities. We can debate the failure of the ‘experiments’ at Sosúa and Buena Tierra, yet there was for sure relative success. Both colonies were founded as places of refuge for thousands of involuntary emigrants fleeing the violence of their homeland. The fact that some refugees were able to escape the Nazi death-grip and begin life anew as farmers in distant lands underscores that very success. In retrospect, both projects had achieved their original goal of saving lives, and have left a model from which one may draw conclusions regarding their failure or a success. The model of agricultural settlement that Rosen successfully used for the Ukraine and Crimea, proved to be difficult to transfer to Bolivia and the Dominican Republic. In spite of Rosen’s agronomist background, Rosenberg’s well-placed connections and professional experience as a lawyer, Hochschild’s wealth, and the help of the military man and Bolivian president Germán Busch, the success of these Jewish agricultural colonies was never assured. It all came down to the individual efforts of a few hardy souls and the collective will of many others behind the scenes. Although the same development model was used among the settlements discussed herein, it is clear that what had worked at one site failed miserably at others.

Competent administration, experimentation with different crops, a willing and able work force, along with the use of cutting-edge technology did not, by any stretch of the imagination, guarantee success. A fascist megalomaniac, a couple of third world dictators, a beloved U.S. President, a Jewish mining magnate and a cast of others, made for some very strange bedfellows indeed. Remove one of these historic figures from the equation, and neither Sosúa nor Buena Tierra would have seen the light of day.As human-converted habitats expand over Earth’s surface, the fate of global biodiversity will depend increasingly on the quality and characteristics of farming landscapes . Agricultural systems vary widely in their ability to support biodiversity, with many species extirpated from some but sustained in others . Additionally, characteristics of the species themselves, evolved over millions of years, may predispose some lineages to benefit from human environmental impacts . Phylogenetic diversity, the total evolutionary history or phylogenetic branch lengths of all species in a community , is recognized as having intrinsic conservation value . Also, ecological experiments in small plots indicate that communities with more phylogenetic diversity are more stable , possess higher productivity , and support more species at other trophic levels . Despite the known impact of agriculture on species loss, how habitat conversion affects phylogenetic diversity remains unknown. Studies of plants and invertebrates have established that local environmental disturbances favor subsets of closely related clades and often result in phylogenetic diversity loss . Further, some studies that examine the global extinction risk of birds and mammals suggest that particular branches of the tree of life are at greater risk than others , although whether evolutionarily distinct species are more at risk than species with many living relatives remains contested . We quantified changes in phylogenetic diversity across multiple landscapes in Costa Rica, combining a recent complete avian phylogeny with temporally and spatially extensive tropical bird censuses to assess how habitat conversion is restructuring the avian phylogeny . The data set comprised 44 transects, surveyed in wet and dry seasons over 12 years across four regions in two biomes .

Transects were located in three land-use types: forest reserves, diversified agricultural systems, and intensive mono cultures. Compared with intensive mono cultures, diversified agricultural systems had more crop types, complex configurations of vegetation, and substantial surrounding tree cover . Our analysis focused on three unresolved questions. First, do certain bird clades thrive in agriculture, or is this capacity broadly distributed across the tree of life? Second, how much phylogenetic diversity is lost when native forest is replaced with agriculture? Last, are evolutionarily distinct species capable of persisting in agriculture? We found that clades from across the bird phylogeny thrived in agriculture . Affinity for different habitats showed phylogenetic signal, meaning that closely related species were more likely to share habitat preferences than species that were distantly related . The phylogenetic signal was best described by using Pagel’s lambda transformation of the phylogeny , which reduces the degree of correlation of traits between species below the Brownian motion expectation . Although most taxonomic families had species associated with all habitat types, some families tended to affiliate with particular habitats. For example, pigeons, seedeaters, swallows, and blackbirds were agriculture-affiliated,rolling bench whereas trogons, antbirds, ovenbirds, and manakins were forest-affiliated . Despite the variety of lineages that were found in agriculture, average within transect phylogenetic diversity was 40% lower in intensive mono cultures than in forest reserves and 15% lower in diversified agricultural systems than in forest reserves . Across all transects and years, forest reserves, diversified agricultural systems, and intensive mono cultures housed 4.10, 3.85, and 3.26 billion years of evolutionary history. Two processes were responsible for changes in phylogenetic diversity: species loss and increasing species relatedness. We found roughly the same number of bird species in diversified agricultural systems as in forest reserves [N = 62 species; likelihood ratio test P = 0.75] but half as many species in intensive mono cultures . However, species loss alone did not account for declining phylogenetic diversity in agriculture . Species in forest reserves were less related to one another than expected by chance, whereas species in diversified agricultural systems and intensive mono cultures were more closely related . These patterns indicate that phylogenetic diversity loss in agriculture occurs in two steps. First,habitat conversion from forest to diversified agricultural systems causes a shift in community composition while maintaining species richness: Agricultural species are not nested subsets of forest species . Because species in diversified agricultural communities are closely related, this shift results in a moderate decline in phylogenetic diversity within a transect. Then, as agricultural practices intensify, species loss from this agricultural bird community causes another more-substantial decline in phylogenetic diversity. Whether phylogenetic diversity loss will substantially reshape the global tree of life depends on the capability of species from evolutionarily distinct lineages to persist in agricultural lands. We quantified each species’ evolutionary distinctness as its contribution to the phylogenetic diversity of the world’s 9993 bird species . Species in forest reserves had slightly greater average evolutionary distinctness than those in diversified agricultural systems or intensive mono cultures . This pattern did not result from a small number of highly distinct, forest affiliated species—repeating the analysis after removing the top 10% most distinct species did not alter results .

Conversely, communities in intensive mono cultures hosted younger species with more-rapid diversification rates  . At the species level after accounting for phylogenetic covariance, DR was negatively correlated with forest affiliation and positively correlated with affinity for diversified agricultural systems . To explore how habitat conversion affects the temporal population dynamics and local extirpation risks of evolutionarily distinct species, we developed a temporal, multi-species, hierarchical occupancy model that accounted for detection bias . The model provided a dynamic assessment of which species were extirpated from and/or recolonized sites at the greatest rates from year to year . Extirpation was estimated as the probability that a species did not persist from one year to the next, whereas colonization was the probability that a species was absent one year but present the next. We modeled occupancy dynamics over 12 years, validating our model through examining dry and wet season surveys separately. We found that extirpation probability was highest in intensive mono cultures and lowest in forest reserves . More evolutionarily distinct species experienced higher extirpation rates than less-distinct species in both diversified agricultural systems and intensive mono cultures. Evolutionarily distinct species fared worst in intensive mono cultures, where the top 10% most distinct species experienced extirpation rates ~two times greater than in diversified agricultural systems. Between-year colonization probabilities were low in all land-use types, but evolutionarily distinct species colonized both diversified agricultural systems and intensive mono cultures less frequently than less-distinct species . Repeating analyses at the genus level confirmed that the results were not driven by a few clades. These findings suggest that, over time, evolutionarily distinct species will face challenges in maintaining populations in agricultural systems, especially in intensive mono cultures. We offer two possible explanations for why evolutionarily distinct species and phylogenetic diversity should decline in agriculture. First, species that today inhabit tropical agriculture may have evolved primarily in open habitats, such as grasslands. During geologically recent periods of glaciation when open grassland habitats in the Neotropics proliferated , several clades may have undergone increased speciation , leading to the enrichment of younger species in agriculture . Indeed, we found that species that use natural open habitats were more likely to thrive in agriculture . However, whereas species associated with savannas had slightly higher diversification rates than other species , there were no consistent differences in diversification rates between species that use natural open habitats and those that do not . Another explanation is that birds in agriculture represent a novel community.

The production of irrigated crops is constrained by water availability and prices

We explore sensitivity to spatially heterogeneous future impacts by incorporating a subset of the 35 yield change scenarios from the AgMIP global gridded crop model intercomparison study into GCAM’s exogenous agricultural assumptions. The scenarios selected have been found to span a range of global impacts in previous GCAM versions. Each GGCM assesses the effects on yields of RCP 8.5 changes in CO2 , temperature, and precipitation from five bias-corrected global circulation models for rainfed and perfectly irrigated versions of crops. Water for irrigation is constrained in the version of GCAM used for analysis. We apply crop impacts in one of two ways: only in the U.S. and everywhere . This work is consistent with earlier work using different models to consider similar scenarios regarding the importance of international impacts, adding robustness to the findings through the use of a different multi-sector model. We find that international impacts could be as important as domestic impacts for the financial value of U.S. agricultural crop production in across spatially and temporally varying agricultural impacts scenarios. Crucially, there are scenarios in which examining only domestic impacts would lead to a fundamentally different analysis of the future of U.S. agricultural crop production than if one considered the combined effects of domestic and international impacts. Therefore, while there is uncertainty about climate impacts on future crop yields, evidence suggests that the importance of international effects on the financial value of U.S. crop production is robust across this uncertainty.GCAM couples human and physical Earth systems to explore the impacts of economic and environmental policies. GCAM is calibrated to historical data through 2010 and then simulates forward from 2010 to 2100 in five year time steps by incorporating changes in quantities such as population, GDP, technology, and policy to produce outputs that include land use, emissions, and commodity prices. Specifically, GCAM can assimilate high spatial resolution information on the global distribution of crop yields and analyze its effects on the coupled system of global agriculture markets. This and previous versions of GCAM track long term trend behavior rather than inter annual variability . All scenarios in this study follow Shared Socioeconomic Pathway 2,vertical farm tower the “middle-of-the-road” socio-economic scenario.

The associated GCAM scenario provides the reference against which we measure impacts in this study. GCAM represents the energy system in 32 economic regions, and it represents global production in 384 agricultural and land-use regions. Each of the 384 land units in GCAM represents a water basin-economic region combination. Twenty-three of these lie within the U.S. With each land unit, GCAM allocates land across more than a dozen types based on cover and use. Allocation is based on a logit formulation to optimize profitability, with details provided in Wise et al . Important to this study, GCAM models production of a range of agricultural commodities , each with four different management types . S1 Fig illustrates the land competition nests used by GCAM v5.2 in each GCAM land unit . S1 Table in the S1 File provides the mappings between crops in the FAOSTAT database and GCAM commodities. Some GCAM commodities are straightforward , but some GCAM commodities are economic aggregates, such as Misc Crop and OilCrop . The span of GCAM commodities allows a relatively full modeling of the agricultural sector of economies. On the supply side of agricultural crop production in GCAM, the “no impacts” baseline yield change assumptions are read in exogenously. These yield changes are used by GCAM to calculate the profitability of a GCAM crop-irrigation-fertilizer combination in each GCAM land unit at each time step. This profitability determines land allocated to each land type . The combination of exogenous yields and endogenous land allocation gives production of each crop-irrigation-management combination in each land unit. Because land shares allocated to rainfed versus irrigated, high versus low fertilizer versions of each crop may change, the aggregate yield for each crop output by GCAM will differ from the input yields. In other words, there is endogenous yield intensification in GCAM. AgMIP yield impacts are incorporated as multipliers on the exogenous yield assumptions used by GCAM .The GCAM food demand system creates a slightly elastic portion of demand for each crop type, based on the exogenous population and GDP assumptions GCAM takes as inputs. Therefore, the minimum quantity defined by the food demand system must be met globally by GCAM agricultural crop production.

Other demand sectors are more elastic. For some GCAM agricultural commodities, such as Corn and Oil Crop, this leads to an overall more elastic total demand function because GCAM explicitly models the energy sector and the accompanying price-sensitive demand for use of these crops as bio-fuels. Crops such as Wheat and Rice that are primarily used to feed humans have nearly perfectly inelastic demand. This lends an extra layer of difficulty to analysis of the dynamics in any particular agricultural impacts scenario. Since both supply and demand schedules may shift, there is never a single mechanism that may be identified for any particular price change. GCAM includes mechanisms on both the supply and demand side that allow for adaptation behavior. Specifically, because there is a price elasticity of demand for GCAM agricultural crop commodities , reduction of quantity demanded is one available mechanism in the model. This includes changing demand for animal feed and bio-energy in response to changing prices. On the supply side, economic agents can endogenously adjust land allocation in response to changes in profit rates between rainfed or irrigated versions of crops . Additionally, the option to shift to higher nitrogen fertilizer per unit of land is included, which leads to an increase in both the yield and the cost per unit of land . Pesticide use is currently not explicitly modeled, and therefore changes to pesticide use are not included as an adaptation option in GCAM. Finally, GCAM includes trade of agricultural crop commodities and the ability for producers to shift land allocation among commodities as profit rates change with yield and price changes. A significant difference between the version of GCAM used in this paper and the version documented in detail, is that GCAM 5.2 features different agricultural crop trade behavior. Previously, GCAM modeled completely flexible trade with nearly all agricultural commodities traded freely on a global market with no explicit distinction between domestically-produced and imported products and a common global market price. The version of GCAM used for this study employs a system that is based on an Armington distinction between domestically-produced and imported products . In this new approach in GCAM, we specify region-specific agricultural markets at the 32-region level. Regional demand is an explicitly modeled choice between domestic production and imports from the global market via a nested logit structure, similar to our modeling of land use allocation in GCAM .

International trade is not modeled as explicit bilateral trade but instead as a single market for each commodity that contains all regional gross imports and gross exports. Additional details may be found in the S1 File.We examine the implications of agricultural impacts to U.S. producers through the use of four varying crop-climate model combinations in the AgMIP/ISIMIP global gridded crop model inter comparison study CO2 fertilization effects, driven by RCP 8.5 earth system changes. RCP 8.5 is a climate scenario that features large changes in temperature, CO2, and precipitation and therefore relatively larger local changes in crop yields produced by crop models than under the other RCPs. It was selected with the idea that the larger yield change signal in RCP 8.5 would aid in identifying the emergent mechanisms that dictate the future economic changes resulting from yield changes. The other RCPs are deserving of future examination, but one would expect that the policies applied to reduce emissions would then interact with the impacts of correspondingly smaller yield changes. The GCAM reference scenario to which these crop yield impacts are applied has no climate policies in place. We use AgMIP global gridded yields from each of the EPIC and LPJmL crop models driven by five GCMs under RCP 8.5. Each scenario models yields for different collections of crops. Further, these collections of crops differ from the commodities modeled in GCAM. Yield data is available for both perfectly irrigated and locally rainfed versions of each crop. These gridded yields are aggregated to the GCAM land units using MIRCA2000 harvested area data for weighting. At the basin scale, time series of yields are converted to multipliers by dividing by the historical baseline average yield for each crop-irrigation-basin combination. Finally, these crop-irrigation-basin specific multipliers are converted from the crop model specific crop types to multipliers for each GCAM commodity irrigation-basin combination using GTAP harvested area weights from the GCAM data system for aggregation. This method for incorporating climate driven yield changes as multipliers on GCAM’s exogenous yield assumptions follows methods used in the broader literature. GCAM’s biomass crop commodity receives the median of impacts to all other commodities,vertical plant tower for each irrigation-management practice combination, in each basin. Fig 1 is a schematic summarizing this processing pipeline. S2 Table in S1 File lists the mapping between AgMIP model crops and GCAM commodities used to estimate multipliers. Corresponding water supply constraints for irrigated crops are used for each scenario. Impacts are not applied to grassland or forest to isolate the role of impacts on crop yields.Results are presented for a variety of physical and economic output variables from GCAM. Due to both the variability and the relatively small sample size of spatially heterogeneous climate-crop impact scenarios available for this paper, summary statistics across scenarios are not presented. Rather, the results presented here focus on relationships between the Domestic and the Full scenarios that emerge in each of the different climate-crop impact combinations considered.

To this end, Figs 2 and 3, and S3 Fig illustrate the percent change relative to the no impacts reference GCAM scenario for several economic and physical variables in 2050 at the aggregate U.S. level for different GCAM commodities, under for all scenarios in the work. Fig 2 focuses results on Corn and OilCrop, globally important commodities for which the U.S. is a major producer. Fig 3 presents results for Rice and Wheat, important commodities with more spatially distributed production across the globe. S3 Fig presents results for the remaining GCAM commodities. The variables plotted include Area allocated to each commodity , the U.S. commodity Price, the production Prod of each commodity , and the aggregate endogenous yield change EndYld . Results are also included for changes in revenue Revto examine an aggregate direction of change between Price and Prod, as both variables are important to U.S. producers.Price changes are a primary economic mechanism through which international yield changes are transmitted to U.S. agricultural producers. Because agricultural commodities are traded across the globe, the prices of these commodities are affected by events that occur both in the U.S. and internationally. An event that affects U.S. yields will have consequences for U.S. production but also for prices in the rest of the world and will therefore affect production throughout the world agricultural system. The reverse also holds. Because the U.S. is a significant but not majority contributor to the global agricultural market for most crops, the magnitude of U.S. price changes in the Domestic is consistently smaller than in the Full scenario, across all climate-crop impact combinations for all GCAM commodities, illustrated in Figs 2 and 3 and S3 Fig. This is regardless of whether prices have increased or decreased relative to the baseline scenario, consistent with many of the results reported. Further, applying impacts in the Full case versus in the Domestic results in differing price changes from reference, even for commodities such as Corn that display very similar values in the Full and Domestic cases for physical variables such as area, production, and endogenous yield. It is possible that the relationship between the Full impacts price change from reference and the Domestic impacts price change from reference may break down as the structure of the system being modeled fundamentally changes. For example, in a more restrictive trade scenario, U.S. producers would be more restricted in their options to respond to future climate and prices would be increasingly dictated solely by the direct impacts on U.S. productivity. For commodities such as Corn and Oil Crop, for which the U.S. is a significant producer and exporter, a major shock only to U.S. production is closer in magnitude to a shock across the entire world than it would be for other commodities.

The nine RWBs use different approaches to assess and control agricultural discharges

Aquifers also help move water from areas of recharge finding to areas dominated by extraction that are miles or — in very large aquifers — a few tens of miles away. Unfortunately, in many areas of California we have not been replenishing this account sufficiently during wet years. Groundwater resources across California’s agricultural regions have been more stressed during the current drought than at any other time in history finding. In most wells, depth to groundwater has exceeded that of the same or nearby wells in the 2007–2009 drought, and exceeds the depths recorded in the mid-20th century, prior to local, state and federal water projects finding coming on-line. The demand for groundwater has been increasing due to the increased acreage of intensively grown crops, large-scale conversion of range land and field crops to permanent crops and uncertainty about water deliveries from the Sacramento-San Joaquin Delta, the heart of California’s elaborate surface water conveyance system finding.Lower groundwater levels have significantly increased pumping costs and increased the need for constructing deeper wells where existing wells were not sufficiently deep to access falling water levels finding. Greater reliance on groundwater during the drought has caused land subsidence on a large scale in the Central Valley finding, coastal basins and Southern California; it has also exacerbated seawater intrusion where pumping occurs in aquifers near the coast finding. As pumping lowers the water table, water quality is sometimes compromised by saline water or other naturally occurring contaminants finding. Rapidly falling water tables also lead to more-contaminated shallow groundwater entering drinking water wells. Agricultural regions in California are challenged not only by dwindling groundwater supplies — a critical drought insurance for California — but also by significant groundwater quality degradation, in particular from nitrate and salt pollution. Pollutants may come from urban sources finding,vertical farm system domestic household sources finding or agricultural sources finding.

A number of studies have shown a high incidence of nitrate, above drinking water standards, in domestic and public drinking water supply wells; in some counties, more than 40% of domestic wells exceed the nitrate limit for safe drinking water finding. Salt accumulation in streams and groundwater has also been found to be significant finding, with potentially punitive economic consequences: By 2030, the combined impact of surface water and groundwater salinization to agriculture and the California economy, if current conditions continue and no preventative action is taken, is estimated at $6 to $10 billion annually in lost production costs, job losses and other impacts finding. The problems of groundwater overdraft and water quality degradation have been recognized for some time. Increasing public concern over the past two decades has raised the level of local, state and federal government engagement and of actions by policy- and decision makers. Groundwater users and wastewater dischargers in the urban and the agricultural sectors face new regulatory requirements. While urban governments have a long history of dealing with limited water resources, the agricultural community is experiencing significant and historic changes in its involvement with managing groundwater extraction and protecting groundwater resources for the future. Based on these principles, the legislation lays out a framework for the entire state to manage its groundwater. In 127 medium- and high-priority groundwater basins finding, groundwater sustainability agencies finding will have to be formed no later than June 2017. These GSAs will be responsible for developing and implementing a groundwater sustainability plan finding that has specific objectives and meets specified sustainability targets consistent with the core principles of the SGMA. GSAs have 3 to 5 years to develop and begin implementing their GSP finding. GSAs must show significant progress in implementing their plan and achieve sustainability no later than 2042.Funding for GSP activities will likely come from a combination of state and local funding sources. In over drafted basins, adjudications may continue to be an alternative process to achieve sustainability, despite the high cost and often years-long legal proceedings involved. As of this writing, the Legislature is actively considering multiple bills that would create an alternative, streamlined adjudication process.

In the intermediate and long run, the main impact from this legislation will be that new recharge and groundwater storage options will be pursued, and, where needed, pumpers may see restrictions in pumping or well drilling. Where additional recharge is available, pumpers may be asked to pay additional costs to secure the recharge needed in return for their right to continue pumping. Basin boundaries may be adjusted and may include fractured rock aquifers currently not recognized as groundwater basins by the Department of Water Resources although they are subject to significant groundwater extraction in some areas. Litigation and state intervention may be inevitable in some cases, but it remains to be seen how frequently that route will be chosen over mediation or facilitated GSP development and implementation. In either case, the new groundwater legislation marks a turning point in California water management by no longer allowing for continued depletion of groundwater resources and by requiring an active, well-informed groundwater management system that is better integrated with surface water management, water quality management and land use decisions to maintain a balance that best serves competing human, economic and environmental health interests.The federal Clean Water Act addresses only surface water quality. By contrast, California’s water quality law, the Porter Cologne Water Quality Control Act of 1969 finding, includes the protection of groundwater quality. The California Legislature designated the State Water Resources Control Board finding and nine newly created regional water boards finding to implement the Porter-Cologne Act. The primary function of the RWBs is to establish a basin plan that identifies water quality goals and to develop regulatory programs to achieve those goals. Non-point sources of potential groundwater pollution finding were long exempted from direct oversight through unconditional waste discharge waivers. However, those waivers were discontinued by the Legislature in 2002, which led to new regulatory requirements for agricultural and other non-point source water dischargers finding. Focused on surface water quality in the first decade after 2002, these regulatory efforts now increasingly address groundwater quality. They require demonstrable source control and documentation of groundwater nitrate and salt discharges and also provide state and federal funds to improve the drinking water supplies of communities affected by poor groundwater quality.

The Central Valley RWB and Central Coast RWB regions are home to large areas of California’s most intensive agricultural operations and have therefore developed the most extensive regulations. But all RWBs are obligated to consider discharges from non-point sources to groundwater and to develop basin plan amendments for nutrient and salt management finding.The 2007 Dairy Order was the first comprehensive California groundwater quality permitting program applicable specifically to farms. It sets the framework for permitting dairy discharges of nutrients and salts to surface water and groundwater. The dairy order requires dairies to prepare nutrient and waste management plans, annually report nutrient budgets for individual fields, tonnage of manure exports and water quality of on-site wells. Targeted shallow groundwater monitoring and efforts to develop improved management practices that demonstrably improve groundwater quality are implemented through the Central Valley Dairy Representative Monitoring Program. This program is led by a coalition of dairy producers that is working closely with the RWB; it offers an efficient alternative to individual dairy groundwater monitoring plans.Upon its inception in the early 2000s, the Central Valley ILRP finding focused on surface water and watershed protection through farmer education, certification and coalition-led stream water quality monitoring and management. But since 2010, the Central Valley RWB has been expanding the ILRP to add elements that also protect and improve groundwater quality, primarily nitrate, pesticide and salt contamination, through source management on irrigated lands. In the Central Valley, the ILRP covers about 7 million irrigated acres with several tens of thousands of individual farms. Permits finding are given either to individual farms or to regional ILRP coalitions, organizations that farms can join to represent them collectively with the RWB. ILRP coalitions representing large groups of farmers include the Sacramento River Watershed, Rice Farmers, Eastern San Joaquin Watershed, San Joaquin County and Delta, Western San Joaquin Watershed, Tulare Lake Basin Area, and Western Tulare Lake Basin Area coalitions. Each coalition is subject to a separate RWB order. Under the expanded ILRP, the first step is a Groundwater Assessment Report finding, which is currently being developed or has been developed by each of the coalitions. The assessment identifies historic and current groundwater quality conditions and identifies vulnerable groundwater regions. The assessment provides the rationale for the monitoring and reporting requirements, which may differ within and between regions, and allows for a tiered program of monitoring and reporting requirements for sub-regions to reflect the diverse potential impacts to groundwater. In a next step, beginning in 2015, field specific nutrient management planning forms will need to be completed by all farmers for the first time. Generally, farmers will now be required to implement management practices, keep appropriate records finding and report some of the information collected to their coalition. The coalitions are further responsible for performing groundwater monitoring, typically in a network of domestic and monitoring wells. As in the dairy program,vertical indoor farming the coalitions are also responsible for developing management practices that demonstrably improve and protect groundwater quality. A significant focus will be on documenting field nitrogen inputs and outputs and on improving nitrogen-use efficiency.In 2012, the Central Coast RWB adopted an update to the ILRP, called the Agricultural Order finding. The program covers about 4,000 farms on about 400,000 acres. Based on its own groundwater assessment work, the RWB created three tiers of farms depending on the potential risk they pose to groundwater quality. The tiers are determined by pesticide use, farm size, nitrate occurrence in nearby public supply and farm wells, and by crop type.

About one in seven farms are in the highest tier, tier three finding, about half of the farms, mostly vineyards, fall in the lowest tier finding, and the remainder are in tier two. As in the Central Valley, farms in all tiers are required to perform proper nutrient, pesticide and irrigation management, documented in their farm plans finding. Back flow prevention and proper well abandonment are also required on all farms. Unlike in the Central Valley ILRP, all farms need to sample groundwater from existing wells twice during the first year. Subsequent groundwater sampling frequency is greater for farms in tier three than in tier two or one. Farms can choose to implement the groundwater sampling program individually or join a coalition that has been created specifically to perform groundwater monitoring and to support farmers with the implementation of the Agricultural Regulatory Program.Operating at an even larger scale and affecting stakeholders beyond agriculture finding is the Central Valley Salinity Alternatives for Long-Term Sustainability finding program. In coordination with the RWB, it was created in 2009 by stakeholders to develop a comprehensive salt and nutrient basin plan amendment for the Central Valley that complies with the state’s recycled water policy finding. The development of the basin plan amendment includes a wide range of assessments by CV-SALTS: nitrate and salt source loading from agricultural, urban and industrial sources, extensive review of surface water and groundwater quality data, and development of potential management practice and infrastructure solutions. The CV-SALTS program builds upon and is coordinated with the Central Valley Dairy Order and ILRP efforts. It focuses in particular on avoiding future salinization of the Central Valley aquifer system under SWRCB’s overarching antidegradation policy. Stakeholders are organized within the Central Valley Salinity Coalition finding, which is scheduled to provide its final salt and nutrient management plan finding to the RWB in 2016. As part of these efforts, a recent Strategic Salt Accumulation and Transport Study finding compared historic water quality data to an assessment of current salt and nutrient loading in the Central Valley; it determined that approximately 1.2 million acre-feet of Central Valley groundwater needs to be desalinized annually to meet long-term irrigation and drinking water standards. SSALTS suggests various alternatives for water treatment, including desalination and evaporation ponds. Implementation costs are estimated to be roughly $70 billion over the next 30 years, of which $20 billion can be raised by selling approximately 1.1 million acrefeet of ultra clean treated water annually to urban areas. These costs include some saline water being disposed of by deep injection and some being stored in salt accumulation areas on the Tulare Lake Bed finding.

The limited extent of ownership change may have limited the effects found in this study

Measuring costs per unit of output, the authors find that privatization increased the efficiency of firms operating in both competitive and non-competitive environments, and that the efficiency gains from privatization were significantly greater in non-competitive environments than in competitive ones.These results provide a uniquely controlled setting in which to study the effect of competition on relative efficiency, and also the relative importance of agency issues and soft budget constraint issues in publicly-owned firms.Since public firms should become less relatively less efficient than prive firms as competition increases, because soft budget constraints shield them from competitive pressures, and relatively more efficient as competition increases, because the observable performance of other firms reduces agency issues, the fact that efficiency gains from privatization attenuated with the level of competition provides evidence that the effects of agency issues dominated the effects of soft budget constraints in this study.The study also documents the existence of subsidies to public firms prior to privatization – amounting to 12.7% of GDP in Mexico – suggesting that reductions in agency-related issues due to competition had to surmount substantial soft budget constraint issues that presumably increased with the level of competition that firms faced.Because La Porta and Lopez-de-Silanes separates ownership effects by competition level, examines a large number of firms, and is exceptionally careful and thorough in its approach, it is one of the most persuasive studies in providing evidence of the effects of competition on ownership efficiency.The vast majority of studies that examine public and private efficiency differences in noncompetitive settings are studies of privatization efforts that compare the performance of enterprises before and after state ownership.

A complication in studying privatization programs is that ownership effects could take place gradually,nft hydroponic and might not be adequately captured just after privatization takes place.Additionally, the announcement of a government’s intentions to privatize sometimes preceded the actual transfer of ownership by several years, during which the perception of ownership transferrability and a period of “shake-out”could increase public firm efficiency.Lastly, privatization programs are typically accompanied by other regulatory changes – in particular, many governments shielded state-owned firms from competition, and undertook market liberalization measures either concurrently with privatization, or after a grace period during which newly privatized firms are shielded from competition.Unless these liberalization effects are separated, studies may compare public monopolies to private firms operating with limited competition, and thus conflate the effects of competition and ownership on efficiency.Of the 9 studies in non-competitive environments in our review, 5 study privatizations of telecommunications firms.Within this industry, Wallsten and Boylaud and Nicoletti both find no ownership effects from privatization, while Ros , Ramamurti , and Boles de Boer and Evans find that private firms are more efficient than state-owned firms.Wallsten studies the privatization of telecom monopolies in 30 countries across Africa and Latin America, from 1984 to 1997.Controlling for competition changes and other concurrent programs that may have affected firm efficiency, he finds no effect of privatization on labor productivity in the absence of additional regulatory measures.When privatized firms are faced with price regulation from an independent regulator, though, privatization yields efficiency benefits.This result is consistent with theory: By keeping prices low, regulators essentially create the pressure for efficiency that competition does, which differentially affects private firms if public firms face soft budget constraints.

Boylaud and Nicoletti study telecom privatizations in 23 OECD countries from 1991 to 1997, and similarly conclude that ownership did not affect labor productivity, when controlling for the level of competition and also the time to liberalization.However, both the number of competitors and decreases in the time to liberalization are associated with increases in productivity.The authors interpret the effects of time to liberalization as being due to the effects of potential competition, which may have stimulated managers and employees in public firms to increase efforts to avoid unemployment as profit margins were reduced.Such responses may be partially attributable to an anticipated reduction in cross subsidization across internal groups, which the authors describe as common prior to privatization.However, diminished agency issues would only occur when actual competitors emerged, and the separately significant effect of the number of competitors provides evidence that agency issues are important.Notable in this study is the fact that the government “generally maintained the largest single share of the PTOs capital and sometimes retained special voting rights in the privatised enterprises.”Indeed, some studies find that ownership change is only effective when firms are fully privatized.Ros , Ramamurti , and Boles de Boer and Evans all find productivity improvements in telecom firms following privatization.Ros studies a mix of firms that were either privatized during the period from 1986 to 1995, or were private throughout the period, and measures ownership effects on labor productivity while controlling for competition.Ramamurti finds significant ownership effects in 3 of 4 telecoms studied, but does not separate competition and ownership effects, and acknowledges that the level of competition may have changed after privatization.Boles de Boer and Evans provide a case study of the 1990 privatization of Telecom New Zealand, and study efficiency changes during the period from 1987, when the market was liberalized, to 1993, when the first actual competitors entered.

As a case study, the evidence the auhtors present is inherently less generalizable than that of other studies.On the other hand, the authors are less restricted to use variables that are common across all firms being studied, and can be precise about the levels of competition and other contextual details of the privatization.The study measures productivity as the level of output per cost of inputs, where inputs include labor, material inputs, and capital.They find that productivity increased by 10% per year during the study period, and that unit costs reduced by 5.8% per year.Like Ramamurti , the authors do not separate the effects of competition and ownership in their examination; however, competitors only emerged in the final year of the study, and potential competition due to deregulation was present throughout.A concern permeating all the telecom studies is that the effects of ownership are averaged across both the monopoly conditions and conditions of limited competition following market liberalization, making it impossible to isolate the precise market conditions under which these effects occur.Caves and Christiansen provides some evidence on ownership effects in a static competitive environment, by comparing two Canadian railroads – one private, one state owned – who were each other’s sole competitors for many decades.Measuring the cost of inputs per unit of output, they find that the state-owned railroad was initially less productive than the private one, but find no significant differences between the two by the end of the 19- year study period.Since the railroads began to compete 30 years prior to the study period, their findings suggest that efficiency improvements may take a very long time to adjust to a change in the level of competition.Assuming this is true, the privatization studies that average efficiency effects across short periods of time during which monopolies were exposed to competition may be best placed as studies reporting relative efficiencies under monopoly conditions.Both Caves and Christiansen and Ramamurti make another contribution to the analysis: While they both study railroads that faced little or no direct competition , both argue that the railroads they study faced substantial indirect presure from other forms of transportation that competed for both passengers and freight.Ramamurti explicitly documents the market share of the Argentinian railroad he studies, and finds that only 8% of freight and intercity travel were handled by the railroad, along with 15-20% of suburban travel.Since ameliorating agency issues requires the observation of direct competitors, both studies exist in a non-competitive environment for agency purposes.However, indirect competitive pressure reduced prices and profit margins, and thus expand the efficiency gap between public and private firms due to soft budget constraints.With both unmitigated agency issues and exacerbated soft budget constraint issues, theory would predict the efficiency gap between these railroads to be at their largest.

Indeed, Ramamurti finds that privatization resulted in a 370% increase in labor productivity,nft system and explicitly documents the existence of railroad subsidies to the state-owned Argentinian railroad prior to privatization.Caves and Christiansen, who paradoxically find no significant differences by the end of their study, also point out that the state’s role was “restricted to that of a stockholder”in their study – no subsidies were provided to the state owned railroad.Both of these studies point to the potential relevance of state subsidies in reducing efficiency gains, particularly in environments where firms face substantial competitive pressure.Ehrlich et al conduct a very careful study of 23 airlines with varying ownership types, and estimate a model wherein productivity is endogenously and separately determined for each airline.The authors include several robustness checks using alternate specifications, and do not consistently find level differences between the cost efficiencies of private and public airlines across all specifications.However, they find that private firms have a relatively higher rate of cost reduction over time in each specification that they test.To examine whether ownership effects vary with competition levels, the authors separately test the efficiency of the subset of airlines in the US, Canada, France, and the UK, arguing that that they exist in competitive environments because there are more domestic competitors within these nations.Although the authors find qualitatively similar results for these airlines, it is unclear whether airlines in those four countries might not face very different competitive environments from airlines that are the sole carriers for their countries, to the extent that airlines compete internationally, and also because – as the authors themselves point out – the International Air Transport Association coordinated fares and erected barriers to entry for all airlines during the period of study.Also notable in this study is the fact that both private and public airlines have historically been subject to soft budget constraints via “bailouts”,so that state-owned airlines may not be subject to a widened efficiency gap at higher competition levels in this industry.Funkhouser and MacAvoy study firms in a variety of industries in Indonesia, and compare their efficiencies by computing the ratio of each firm’s average costs to the appropriate industry average.Although they find no differences at the 5% level, private firms are significantly more efficient at the 10% level.Cullinane, Song, and Gray use a method that is increasingly popular in the recent literature to estimate cost efficiency: stochastic production frontier function estimation.Rather than looking at the cost of producing a unit of each output separately, or creating an index to evaluate the cost of all outputs simultaneously, the method establishes an efficient frontier of production using the data available, and evaluates each firm’s efficiency based on its distance from the frontier.The authors study 15 container ports in Asia, and find no significant differences in efficiency based on ownership.Of the 7 studies reviewed that study competitive environments, only 3 found that private firms were more efficient than state-owned firms.Of those 3, Vining and Boardman and Diboky both used measures of efficiency that are sensitive to revenue gains; it is unclear whether the measures used in Chen and Yeh are price-sensitive or not.As the evidence in Section 1.3.1 suggests, the efficiency of private firms may be overstated using price-sensitive measures, when markets are not highly competitive.Diboky and Chen and Yeh are similar in other respects.Both studies use Data Envelopment Analysis to estimate the technical efficiency of public and private firms that contemporaneously exist over the study period.Diboky studies results for 300 insurance firms in Germany that compete directly with each other; Chen and Yeh examine 34 domestic banks in Taiwan that face additional competition from 67 banks that are partially foreign-owned.Diboky measures firm “outputs”as gross premiums and net income, while Chen and Yeh measure quantities of loan services and portfolio investment.Chen and Yeh find that private banks outperform public banks; Diboky finds that public banks were substantially less efficient than either private or “mutual”banks of mixed public and private ownership.Vining and Boardman study a variety of industries whose four-firm concentration ratios vary from 14% to 43%, suggesting that the competitive environment in their study bordered on monopolistic competition, by the standards of this review.In such an environment, their use of efficiency metrics such as sales per employee and sales per asset may have caused private firms to appear more efficient than state-owned firms for reasons of higher prices, rather than lower unit costs.

Agriculture plays a central role in many important and influential hypotheses about human history

Greater effective soil age in little-eroded uplands soils means a longer time for the accumulation of recalcitrant organic matter in older soils—and probably more importantly, it allows the accumulation of noncrystalline minerals that stabilize soil organic matter.We further suggest that the patterns for total P are more complex because its pools reflect both weathering and loss and retention by both organic matter and mineral adsorption, which are greater in the upland slope positions.Overall, these results illustrate that erosion and deposition have a rejuvenating effect on the supply of rock-derived nutrients in these valley landscapes —one that suffices to make both lower slope and alluvial soils fertile enough to support intensive pre-contact agricultural systems in both valleys despite the infertility of the upland soils surrounding them.However,differences in the structures of the valleys influenced their ability to support intensive agriculture prior to European contact.Halawa Valley and other large valleys on older islands have well-developed colluvial aprons surrounding their alluvial floors.In contrast, Pololu¯ Valley lacked the potential for lower-slope rainfed agriculture because the high subsidence rate of Hawai’i Island causes a sharp transition between slopes too steep to cultivate and the nearly flat valley floor —a process that is accentuated by the rapid glacial-melt-driven sea level rise of the past approximately 20 ky.Other major valleys on Kohala Volcano have similar structures—including the largest, Waipi’o Valley, which was a major center of precontact Hawaiian settlement.Considering only the area bounded by the cliff tops on the valley sides and waterfalls at the head of the valleys,flood and drain table differences in subsidence rates and corresponding in-fill histories cause large differences in the distribution of slopes suitable for agriculture within Pololu¯ and Halawa.

Assuming that slopes of less than 5 could have been made suitable for intensive pond field systems, 17% of the 423 ha surface of Pololu¯ Valley could support pond fields ; only 6% of the 692 ha surface of Halawa Valley had slopes less than 5.Further, assuming that 12 represents an upper threshold for intensive rainfed agriculture, 16% of Halawa Valley has slopes between 5 and 12 , as opposed to only 5% of Pololu¯ Valley.Available archaeological evidence for pre-contact agricultural systems in Pololu¯ and Halawa is consistent with our findings on valley topography and soil fertility.Tuggle and Tomonari-Tuggle found evidence for both irrigated and rainfed fields on the flat alluvial floor of Pololu¯.They attribute the fact that not all the Pololu¯ alluvium was irrigated to the valley’s hydrologic conditions; the valley floor is so large relative to its watershed area that stream flow was inadequate to have watered the entire valley floor.In Halawa Valley, the entire area of alluvium was converted to irrigated pond fields, which also extended onto the lower colluvial slopes.More importantly, well-defined rainfed cultivation plots with stone-faced terraces and walls extend well up the colluvial slopes in Halawa, encompassing an area greater than the total area of irrigated pond fields there.Rosendahl mapped the Kapana area of Halawa Valley, providing a detailed example of intensive rainfed agricultural terraces, integrated with habitation sites and small temples.Significantly, mid-nineteenth century land records from Halawa demonstrate that most claimants included both irrigated as well as rainfed areas in their claims , showing that the two kinds of agriculture were integral parts of the overall production system at the household level.The broader implications of this potential for intensive rainfed agriculture on colluvial slopes of the valleys on the older islands in the Hawaiian Archipelago are substantial.Analyses of the distribution of intensive agricultural systems and their consequences for the dynamics of Hawaiian society have considered irrigated and rainfed systems to have been spatially separated, due to the very different ecosystem and landscape properties that favor their development.

Because these types of agricultural systems differ both in their ability to produce a surplus over agricultural labor and in their vulnerability to drought—with both comparisons favoring the irrigated pond field systems—these contrasting systems could have contributed to the development of rather different societies, in areas or on islands dominated by one system or the other.The islands of Hawai’i and to a lesser extent Maui were based largely upon intensive rainfed systems, with only a few well-watered irrigated valleys.In contrast, the older islands in the archipelago have been thought to be based mostly upon irrigated pond field systems.However, the evidence here suggests that the older islands likely maintained integrated pond- field/rainfed systems and that, as in Halawa Valley, the peripheral rainfed systems could have covered a larger area than did irrigated pond fields.A similar pattern has been suggested in the leeward Makaha Valley of O’ahu, where archaeological survey confirmed the presence of extensive areas of dryland gardening on colluvial slopes, but where irrigation was confined to smaller areas in the valley interior.The potential for developing integrated pond- field/rainfed systems on colluvial slopes on the older islands strengthens the contrast between the agricultural production potential of Hawai’i Island versus the older islands.It has been suggested that pressures to maintain surplus production in rainfed, drought-prone agricultural areas could have driven the elites of Hawai’i Island towards marriage alliances with elites of the older islands, and/or towards conquest of those islands —and the development of integrated pond field/rainfed systems on the older islands would only have increased their attractiveness as potential acquisitions.Moreover, integrated systems on the older islands could have boosted their potential agricultural yields, and the diversity of foods they could produce, to levels approaching the total productivity of the much larger island of Hawai’i.These dynamics should be incorporated into our understanding of the dynamics of Hawaiian society, and those of other indigenous societies in which similar dynamics could occur.For the vast majority of our evolutionary history, humans subsisted by hunting animals and gathering plants.

Around 12,000 years ago, we began to take a more direct role in the process of food production, domesticating animals and cultivating crops in order to meet our nutritional requirements.This subsistence revolution is thought to have occurred independently in a limited number of places.This new way of life is arguably the most important process in human history, and its dramatic consequences have set the scene for the world we live in today.Agricultural productivity, and its variation in space and time, plays a fundamental role in many theories of human social evolution, yet we often lack systematic information about the productivity of past agricultural systems on a scale large enough to test these theories properly.Here, we outline how explicit crop yield models can be combined with high quality historical and archaeological information about past societies in order to infer how agricultural productivity and potential have changed temporally and geographically.The paper has the following structure: First, we introduce the ways in which agriculture is involved in theories about human social evolution, and stress the need to scientifically test between competing hypotheses.Second, we outline what information we need to model about past agricultural systems and how potential agricultural productivity and carrying capacity can provide a useful way of comparing societies in different regions and time periods.Third, we discuss the need for a systematic, comparative framework for collecting data about past societies.We introduce a new databank initiative we have developed for collating the best available historical and archaeological evidence.We discuss the kinds of coded information we are collecting about agricultural techniques and practices in order to inform our modelling efforts.We illustrate this task by presenting three short case studies summarizing what is known about agricultural systems in three different regions at various time periods.We discuss the challenges confronting this approach, and the various limitations and caveats that apply to the task at hand.Fourth, we outline how we can combine a statistical approach of modelling past crop productivity based on climate inputs with the kind of historical information we are collecting.The development of agriculture and the ways it has spread and intensified are fundamental to our understanding of the human past.For example, authors such as Renfrew, Bellwood, and Diamond argue that early agricultural societies enjoyed a demographic advantage over hunter-gatherers, which fueled a series of population expansions resulting in agriculturalists spreading out to cover much of the world, taking their culture and languages along with them.At the beginning of the European age of exploration, agricultural societies had pushed the distribution of forager populations in the Old World to only those places that were marginal for agriculture.

Widespread forager populations were present in the Americas and Australia, but these too eventually gave way to agricultural populations of European origin.Agriculture raised the carrying capacity of the regions in which it developed and spread,rolling bench leading to people living at higher densities with a more sedentary way-of-life than was previously possible.However, the development of agriculture did not stop there.Further improvements in agricultural technologies and techniques, and processes such as artificial selection further raised the productivity of agriculture and the size of the population that could be supported in any one region.These improvements ultimately enabled humans to live in large urban conglomerations with extremely high population densities.Influential models of agricultural innovation, starting with the work of Esther Boserup , argue that advances occur in response to increases in population, and the subsequent decreasing availability of land.This drives farmers to invest more labor in producing food.In other words, there is feedback in the system that leads to the increasing intensification of agriculture.These processes of intensification, whatever their cause, can occur in a number of different ways and have had important consequences.From the fields and hedgerows of Northern Europe to the mountainside rice terraces of the Ifugao of the Philippines , through to the deforested slopes of Easter Island , agricultural populations have dramatically altered the landscapes around them.Agriculture is central to many theories about how larger-scale complex societies evolved.Under functionalist views of social complexity more productive agricultural systems allowed for ‘surplus’ production, and enabled a more extensive division of labor.This surplus production allowed for individuals who did not grow their own food, enabling the creation of specialized managers and rulers, and occupational artists and artisans.It is argued that this division of labor increases efficiency and coordination, enabling more complex societies to out-compete less complex societies either directly or indirectly.Under this view, not only is a rich resource base a necessary condition for the emergence of complex societies, but it is also a sufficient one.If this is correct, it follows that differences in agricultural productivity can explain why some regions developed more complex societies than others.Changes in agricultural intensity have also been linked to changes in the ritual and religious life of human groups.It is argued that hunter-gathers and early agriculturalists, who lived in small groups and faced high risks from hunting of large animals, tended to participate in dysphoric, “imagistic” rituals that, although rarely experienced, are typically emotionally intense.Such rituals act as a mechanism for creating social cohesion via ‘identity fusion’.A greater dependence on agriculture led to increased group sizes, and required different forms of cooperation and coordination in order to successfully produce food.New ritual forms developed that were organized around daily or weekly cycles but with less intense emotional experiences.It is argued that this ‘routinization’ enabled strangers to recognize and identify with others as members of a common in-group, enabling trust and cooperation on a hitherto unknown scale.It is clear that agriculture is of fundamental importance to studies of the human past.The ideas outlined above represent just a flavor of the ways agriculture and agricultural productivity enter into our understanding of the long-term patterns and processes of human history.

Importantly, these ideas are hypotheses that require testing against other plausible narratives.For example, it has been argued that an important factor driving the evolution of complex societies was intensive forms of conflict between nomadic pastoralists and settled agrarian societies that selected for increasingly larger and more cohesive societies.Thus, complex societies tended to emerge on the border of the Eurasian Steppe and spread out from there.Under this view, agriculture is seen as necessary but not sufficient to explain the observed variation about where and when such societies developed.When attempting to understand the past we should seek to test between competing hypotheses, rather than simply focusing on a single favored idea.In order to do this, it is important to have relevant data on past agricultural systems and their productivity and potential.These systems exhibit a great deal of variation, and are of varying levels of intensity.To enable more direct comparisons across different regions and time periods, it will be important to have explicit models that translate different agricultural systems across space and time into a common currency.This will allow us to perform statistical analyses so that we can directly test alternative hypotheses.