The nine RWBs use different approaches to assess and control agricultural discharges

Aquifers also help move water from areas of recharge finding to areas dominated by extraction that are miles or — in very large aquifers — a few tens of miles away. Unfortunately, in many areas of California we have not been replenishing this account sufficiently during wet years. Groundwater resources across California’s agricultural regions have been more stressed during the current drought than at any other time in history finding. In most wells, depth to groundwater has exceeded that of the same or nearby wells in the 2007–2009 drought, and exceeds the depths recorded in the mid-20th century, prior to local, state and federal water projects finding coming on-line. The demand for groundwater has been increasing due to the increased acreage of intensively grown crops, large-scale conversion of range land and field crops to permanent crops and uncertainty about water deliveries from the Sacramento-San Joaquin Delta, the heart of California’s elaborate surface water conveyance system finding.Lower groundwater levels have significantly increased pumping costs and increased the need for constructing deeper wells where existing wells were not sufficiently deep to access falling water levels finding. Greater reliance on groundwater during the drought has caused land subsidence on a large scale in the Central Valley finding, coastal basins and Southern California; it has also exacerbated seawater intrusion where pumping occurs in aquifers near the coast finding. As pumping lowers the water table, water quality is sometimes compromised by saline water or other naturally occurring contaminants finding. Rapidly falling water tables also lead to more-contaminated shallow groundwater entering drinking water wells. Agricultural regions in California are challenged not only by dwindling groundwater supplies — a critical drought insurance for California — but also by significant groundwater quality degradation, in particular from nitrate and salt pollution. Pollutants may come from urban sources finding,vertical farm system domestic household sources finding or agricultural sources finding.

A number of studies have shown a high incidence of nitrate, above drinking water standards, in domestic and public drinking water supply wells; in some counties, more than 40% of domestic wells exceed the nitrate limit for safe drinking water finding. Salt accumulation in streams and groundwater has also been found to be significant finding, with potentially punitive economic consequences: By 2030, the combined impact of surface water and groundwater salinization to agriculture and the California economy, if current conditions continue and no preventative action is taken, is estimated at $6 to $10 billion annually in lost production costs, job losses and other impacts finding. The problems of groundwater overdraft and water quality degradation have been recognized for some time. Increasing public concern over the past two decades has raised the level of local, state and federal government engagement and of actions by policy- and decision makers. Groundwater users and wastewater dischargers in the urban and the agricultural sectors face new regulatory requirements. While urban governments have a long history of dealing with limited water resources, the agricultural community is experiencing significant and historic changes in its involvement with managing groundwater extraction and protecting groundwater resources for the future. Based on these principles, the legislation lays out a framework for the entire state to manage its groundwater. In 127 medium- and high-priority groundwater basins finding, groundwater sustainability agencies finding will have to be formed no later than June 2017. These GSAs will be responsible for developing and implementing a groundwater sustainability plan finding that has specific objectives and meets specified sustainability targets consistent with the core principles of the SGMA. GSAs have 3 to 5 years to develop and begin implementing their GSP finding. GSAs must show significant progress in implementing their plan and achieve sustainability no later than 2042.Funding for GSP activities will likely come from a combination of state and local funding sources. In over drafted basins, adjudications may continue to be an alternative process to achieve sustainability, despite the high cost and often years-long legal proceedings involved. As of this writing, the Legislature is actively considering multiple bills that would create an alternative, streamlined adjudication process.

In the intermediate and long run, the main impact from this legislation will be that new recharge and groundwater storage options will be pursued, and, where needed, pumpers may see restrictions in pumping or well drilling. Where additional recharge is available, pumpers may be asked to pay additional costs to secure the recharge needed in return for their right to continue pumping. Basin boundaries may be adjusted and may include fractured rock aquifers currently not recognized as groundwater basins by the Department of Water Resources although they are subject to significant groundwater extraction in some areas. Litigation and state intervention may be inevitable in some cases, but it remains to be seen how frequently that route will be chosen over mediation or facilitated GSP development and implementation. In either case, the new groundwater legislation marks a turning point in California water management by no longer allowing for continued depletion of groundwater resources and by requiring an active, well-informed groundwater management system that is better integrated with surface water management, water quality management and land use decisions to maintain a balance that best serves competing human, economic and environmental health interests.The federal Clean Water Act addresses only surface water quality. By contrast, California’s water quality law, the Porter Cologne Water Quality Control Act of 1969 finding, includes the protection of groundwater quality. The California Legislature designated the State Water Resources Control Board finding and nine newly created regional water boards finding to implement the Porter-Cologne Act. The primary function of the RWBs is to establish a basin plan that identifies water quality goals and to develop regulatory programs to achieve those goals. Non-point sources of potential groundwater pollution finding were long exempted from direct oversight through unconditional waste discharge waivers. However, those waivers were discontinued by the Legislature in 2002, which led to new regulatory requirements for agricultural and other non-point source water dischargers finding. Focused on surface water quality in the first decade after 2002, these regulatory efforts now increasingly address groundwater quality. They require demonstrable source control and documentation of groundwater nitrate and salt discharges and also provide state and federal funds to improve the drinking water supplies of communities affected by poor groundwater quality.

The Central Valley RWB and Central Coast RWB regions are home to large areas of California’s most intensive agricultural operations and have therefore developed the most extensive regulations. But all RWBs are obligated to consider discharges from non-point sources to groundwater and to develop basin plan amendments for nutrient and salt management finding.The 2007 Dairy Order was the first comprehensive California groundwater quality permitting program applicable specifically to farms. It sets the framework for permitting dairy discharges of nutrients and salts to surface water and groundwater. The dairy order requires dairies to prepare nutrient and waste management plans, annually report nutrient budgets for individual fields, tonnage of manure exports and water quality of on-site wells. Targeted shallow groundwater monitoring and efforts to develop improved management practices that demonstrably improve groundwater quality are implemented through the Central Valley Dairy Representative Monitoring Program. This program is led by a coalition of dairy producers that is working closely with the RWB; it offers an efficient alternative to individual dairy groundwater monitoring plans.Upon its inception in the early 2000s, the Central Valley ILRP finding focused on surface water and watershed protection through farmer education, certification and coalition-led stream water quality monitoring and management. But since 2010, the Central Valley RWB has been expanding the ILRP to add elements that also protect and improve groundwater quality, primarily nitrate, pesticide and salt contamination, through source management on irrigated lands. In the Central Valley, the ILRP covers about 7 million irrigated acres with several tens of thousands of individual farms. Permits finding are given either to individual farms or to regional ILRP coalitions, organizations that farms can join to represent them collectively with the RWB. ILRP coalitions representing large groups of farmers include the Sacramento River Watershed, Rice Farmers, Eastern San Joaquin Watershed, San Joaquin County and Delta, Western San Joaquin Watershed, Tulare Lake Basin Area, and Western Tulare Lake Basin Area coalitions. Each coalition is subject to a separate RWB order. Under the expanded ILRP, the first step is a Groundwater Assessment Report finding, which is currently being developed or has been developed by each of the coalitions. The assessment identifies historic and current groundwater quality conditions and identifies vulnerable groundwater regions. The assessment provides the rationale for the monitoring and reporting requirements, which may differ within and between regions, and allows for a tiered program of monitoring and reporting requirements for sub-regions to reflect the diverse potential impacts to groundwater. In a next step, beginning in 2015, field specific nutrient management planning forms will need to be completed by all farmers for the first time. Generally, farmers will now be required to implement management practices, keep appropriate records finding and report some of the information collected to their coalition. The coalitions are further responsible for performing groundwater monitoring, typically in a network of domestic and monitoring wells. As in the dairy program,vertical indoor farming the coalitions are also responsible for developing management practices that demonstrably improve and protect groundwater quality. A significant focus will be on documenting field nitrogen inputs and outputs and on improving nitrogen-use efficiency.In 2012, the Central Coast RWB adopted an update to the ILRP, called the Agricultural Order finding. The program covers about 4,000 farms on about 400,000 acres. Based on its own groundwater assessment work, the RWB created three tiers of farms depending on the potential risk they pose to groundwater quality. The tiers are determined by pesticide use, farm size, nitrate occurrence in nearby public supply and farm wells, and by crop type.

About one in seven farms are in the highest tier, tier three finding, about half of the farms, mostly vineyards, fall in the lowest tier finding, and the remainder are in tier two. As in the Central Valley, farms in all tiers are required to perform proper nutrient, pesticide and irrigation management, documented in their farm plans finding. Back flow prevention and proper well abandonment are also required on all farms. Unlike in the Central Valley ILRP, all farms need to sample groundwater from existing wells twice during the first year. Subsequent groundwater sampling frequency is greater for farms in tier three than in tier two or one. Farms can choose to implement the groundwater sampling program individually or join a coalition that has been created specifically to perform groundwater monitoring and to support farmers with the implementation of the Agricultural Regulatory Program.Operating at an even larger scale and affecting stakeholders beyond agriculture finding is the Central Valley Salinity Alternatives for Long-Term Sustainability finding program. In coordination with the RWB, it was created in 2009 by stakeholders to develop a comprehensive salt and nutrient basin plan amendment for the Central Valley that complies with the state’s recycled water policy finding. The development of the basin plan amendment includes a wide range of assessments by CV-SALTS: nitrate and salt source loading from agricultural, urban and industrial sources, extensive review of surface water and groundwater quality data, and development of potential management practice and infrastructure solutions. The CV-SALTS program builds upon and is coordinated with the Central Valley Dairy Order and ILRP efforts. It focuses in particular on avoiding future salinization of the Central Valley aquifer system under SWRCB’s overarching antidegradation policy. Stakeholders are organized within the Central Valley Salinity Coalition finding, which is scheduled to provide its final salt and nutrient management plan finding to the RWB in 2016. As part of these efforts, a recent Strategic Salt Accumulation and Transport Study finding compared historic water quality data to an assessment of current salt and nutrient loading in the Central Valley; it determined that approximately 1.2 million acre-feet of Central Valley groundwater needs to be desalinized annually to meet long-term irrigation and drinking water standards. SSALTS suggests various alternatives for water treatment, including desalination and evaporation ponds. Implementation costs are estimated to be roughly $70 billion over the next 30 years, of which $20 billion can be raised by selling approximately 1.1 million acrefeet of ultra clean treated water annually to urban areas. These costs include some saline water being disposed of by deep injection and some being stored in salt accumulation areas on the Tulare Lake Bed finding.

The fuel subsidies are “cheap fuel” policies used by the government to buy political support

The U.S. Department of Homeland Security finding deports about 400,000 unauthorized foreigners a year. The main target of internal enforcement efforts are foreigners who committed U.S. crimes, but DHS agents take into custody other unauthorized foreigners they encounter when searching for criminals. Under the Secure Communities program, state and local police share the fingerprints of persons they arrest with DHS, which can ask police to hold suspected unauthorized foreigners. If federal enforcement and state laws reduce the availability of unauthorized farm workers, can farmers hire legal guest workers? The H-2A program allows farmers to request certification from the U.S. Department of Labor finding to employ legal guest workers. DOL certified over 95% of employer requests for H-2A workers within 45 days, allowing over 7,000 farm employers to fill almost 95,000 jobs with H-2A workers in 2010. In some cases, one H-2A worker fills more than one U.S. farm job in the United States; the number of visas issued to H-2A workers averages 55,000 a year. In order to be certified to employ H-2A workers, farm employers must try to recruit U.S. workers by posting the job with a State Workforce Agency and advertising it in local media. Employers record the reasons why the U.S. workers who responded to the job offer were not hired. In many cases, U.S. workers seeking farm jobs want to go to work right away, not 30 days in the future, so many U.S. workers who are hired do not show up when the employer calls them to go to work. Employers must offer the higher of the federal or state minimum wage, the prevailing wage in the area, or the adverse effect wage rate finding—the average hourly earnings of crop and livestock workers reported by farm employers to USDA’s NASS during the previous year. The AEWR, which ranges from $9 to $12 an hour, is usually the highest of the three wages. In addition to offering the higher than-minimum wage AEWR, farmers seeking DOL certification to employ H-2A workers must offer free and approved housing to out-of-area U.S. workers and H-2A workers.

This housing requirement is difficult to satisfy in California and other states where labor-intensive farming occurs largely in metro counties. Most farmers in such areas do not offer housing to their employees, and zoning laws make it hard to construct new farm worker housing. Requirements for supervised recruitment,barley fodder system the AEWR, and providing housing for workers convinced many farmers, especially in California, that the H-2A program is “unworkable.” Farmers supported bills in Congress during the 1990s that would have created alternative guest worker programs that eliminated the search for U.S. workers, reduced the AEWR, and eliminated the housing requirement. These guest worker bills were not enacted. However, in December 2000, after the elections of Presidents Fox and Bush, both of whom embraced legalization for unauthorized workers and new guest worker programs, farm worker advocates and farm employers negotiated the Agricultural Job Opportunity Benefits and Security Act finding. AgJOBS would legalize unauthorized foreigners who have done farm work, and make it easier for farm employers to hire guest workers under the H-2A program, repeating the legalization and guest worker changes of IRCA in 1986.AgJOBS was not enacted despite bipartisan support. Instead, Republicans in Congress and states introduced bills and enacted laws that use an enforcement-first strategy to deal with unauthorized migration. As Table 1 shows, more crop farmers in California and throughout the U.S. have turned to labor contractors to obtain workers; employment has been stable, but an increasing share of workers are brought to farms by labor contractors and other intermediaries who are willing to act as risk absorbers in the event of labor and immigration law enforcement. However, stepped-up enforcement of current laws without a new or revised guest worker program could leave agriculture with too few workers. Republicans in Congress who want to increase enforcement are trying to deal with labor shortage concerns by making it easier for farmers to hire legal guest workers under new programs.

The American Specialty Agriculture Act finding would retain the current H-2A program and provide up to 500,000 new H-2C visas a year to foreign farm workers who could stay in the United States up to 10 months a year. To hire H-2C workers, farmers could simply attest that they are abiding by program regulations rather than engage in supervised recruitment, and they could give H-2C workers housing vouchers rather than provide them with housing. H-2C workers could be paid the higher of the federal or state minimum wage or the prevailing wage rather than the AEWR. The second approach to make it easier for farmers to hire legal guest workers is the Legal Agricultural Workforce Act finding, which would grant an unlimited number of 10-month W-visas to foreigners who could move from one farm employer to another. Farm employers certified by USDA to hire W-visa workers would pay Social Security and the Federal Unemployment Insurance taxes on the wages of W-visa workers to cover the cost of administering the program. W-visa workers would pay for their own transportation and housing in the United States, but would receive a refund of their Social Security contributions as an incentive to return home. None of the bills mandating E-Verify or creating new guest worker programs is likely to be enacted in 2012. This means that a major farm labor challenge arises from the effects of long-time federal and new state enforcement efforts. For example, fences and vehicle barriers have been erected on one-third of the 2,000 mile Mexico-U.S. border, slowing the influx of unauthorized Mexicans and other foreigners; only 375,000 were apprehended in FY2011—down from 1.2 million in FY2006. Deportations of foreigners, almost 400,000 in FY2011, exceeded the number of foreigners apprehended just inside U.S. borders for the first time. Fewer new entrants means fewer new farm workers, since many rural Mexicans find their first U.S. job in agriculture. If states require employers to check new hires with E-Verify, and if state and local police detain the persons they encounter who do not have proof of their legal status, farm employers may find fewer new workers appearing to replace those who move on to non-farm jobs.Agriculture is at another farm labor crossroads. The question is whether the next few years will turn out to be like the mid-1960s, when the end of the Bracero program ushered in a 15-year era of rapidly rising wages, mechanization, and union activities. Or will the coming years be more like the late 1980s, when legalization, continued unauthorized migration, and the spread of labor contractors, custom harvesters, and other intermediaries negated the effects of federal employer sanctions laws, allowing the employment of unauthorized workers to increase.

Farmers are reacting to the Congressional stalemate on immigration and new enforcement efforts in different ways. Some are constructing housing for farm workers and beginning to hire workers under the current H-2A program, reasoning that investments in foreign worker recruitment and housing will provide legal and stable workers. Others hope to persuade Congress and state legislatures to exempt agriculture from new immigration enforcement efforts and create new guest worker programs.Concerns about the high price of oil, energy security, and balance of trade, combined with the desire to reduce greenhouse-gas finding emissions and enhance rural development, led to a wide array of policies supporting bio-fuel production in the United States and the European Union finding. These included the American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 as well as the consumption of bio-fuels as part of renewable fuel polices, such as the California and the EU renewable fuel standards. A large body of literature analyzed the impacts of these policies on fuel and food markets and their optimality. However, some of the studies analyzing the impacts of bio-fuel on the fuel markets assume that they are competitive without special attention to the behavior of the Organization for Petroleum Exporting Countries finding and their impacts. In this paper we present the results of research that aim to model OPEC’s behavior and how OPEC’s behavior will affect the price impact of bio-fuel on fuel prices and GHG emissions.In the 1960s, OPEC was founded to unify and coordinate members’ petroleum policies. Currently, it has 12 members, including major oil producers, such as Saudi Arabia, Iran, Iraq, Venezuela, and Nigeria, which control more than 50% of the known oil reserve and produce 42% of the crude-oil production. The organization uses its market power to control production and pricing of oil with varying degrees of effectiveness. Figure 1 depicts OPEC’s revenues through 2008 and suggests that OPEC members’ revenues peaked in the late 1970s and in the new millennium. The increase in oil revenues in the new millennium was a result of an increase in global demand for crude oil from 2000 to 2008,hydroponic barley fodder system associated with a slow increase in supplies, which led to a rapid increase in the price of crude oil during the same period. Although prices more than quadrupled, OPEC production during 1998–2010 increased by an average of only 0.6% a year and the exports grew by only 0.2% a year. The slow growth in production may reflect either slow expansion of supply or more discipline exercised by the cartel members.

Some of the revenue of OPEC countries has been allocated to subsidize fuel prices domestically, as consumers of gasoline and diesel in OPEC countries pay significantly lower prices at the pump compared to the rest of the world. In 2006 average super gasoline prices in non-OPEC countries were 1.04 USD per liter, including an average base retail price of 0.63 USD per liter and extra domestic fees of 0.41 USD per liter, whereas in OPEC countries they averaged only 0.28 USD, which reflects a subsidy of 0.35 USD per liter. We computed the subsidy or tax equivalent levied on gasoline at the fuel pump compared to a benchmark export gasoline price, and the results are depicted in Figure 2. The figure illustrates the widening of the gap between gasoline prices in the oil-importing countries and OPEC countries in the new millennium. During this period, nominal gasoline subsidies in OPEC countries increased while crude-oil prices grew by more than 500% and gasoline prices in the rest of the world surged. Another perspective of fuel pricing is presented in Figure 3. It depicts average gasoline and diesel prices in both OPEC countries and in the rest of the world. From 1993 to 2000, the gap between prices in OPEC countries and the rest of the world was stable but, after 2000, the gap began to grow at an increasing rate as OPEC intensified the utilization of its monopoly power. The pricing patterns presented above suggest that OPEC countries exercise their market power so that the outcomes of crude-oil and transport-fuel markets deviate from the competitive outcome. Under this equilibrium, output is determined by equating supply and demand and the price is equal to the marginal cost of production—the cost of producing the marginal finding unit sold. Several studies model OPEC as if it were a cartel of firms and suggest that it sets prices to maximize profits for its members so that the quantity sold is below the competitive level and the price is above the competitive price and the marginal cost of production. However, a monopolistic firm will not subsidize a group of consumers as OPEC does. So we model OPEC as a cartel of nations. Such cartels are run by politicians who consider the gains of producers finding from profits finding, and the gains of consumers finding from the gap between the benefits of fuel and the price paid for it. Therefore, a cartel of nations will charge consumers in an importing nation a profit-maximizing monopoly price while subsidizing the domestic consumers. The subsidy depends on the relative weight given to producers’ versus the consumers’ surplus. Our empirical analysis suggests that, on average, equal weight is given to the welfare of the two groups but there are differences in the subsidizations among countries finding.They are akin to the widely used “cheap food” policies but, unlike cheap food policies that aim to placate the poor, the cheap fuel policies are targeted to buy the good will of the middle class.

The fundamental welfare question is therefore whether the total benefits to farmers exceed this amount

Our pre-analysis plan, written in 2015, refers to a number of forms analysis that we do not present. For transparency, we describe them briefly here. First, we had intended to conduct an experiment to test credit constraints among traders by offering loans to a randomly selected subset of Commission Agents. We conducted a pilot for this experiment in the first season, issuing 62 short-term working capital loans to a group randomly selected from 124 CAs who expressed a desire for credit. In the end, the repayment rate on these loans was poor finding and our partner decided not to move this experiment to the intended scale, so we do not analyze it. Our PAP specifies a set of hypotheses about convergence between spokes and hubs, and the differential effect of treatment for spokes in which the hub is and is not treated. In the end we were only able to map 84% of our spokes to hubs, and the analysis conducted within this reduced sample is typically inconclusive, suggesting that the trading networks may be more complex than our simple hub-and-spoke mapping supposed. So while we emphasize deviations from the superhub in the text, we do not present analysis relative to hubs. The operating cost for running the platform during the three years of the project was ✩927,190. Making up these costs were program administration, including compensation for managers at IPA and AgriNet, along with the deal coordinators and the program staff in the field, was ✩560,112. Targeting, including call center operations and all village-level promotion activities, cost ✩168,105. Participant training of CAs and AN supervisors was ✩39,784. Program material costs, including airtime costs and the money required to run the guarantee system, were ✩53,648. Monitoring costs, primarily the eight staff members who supervised transactions on the ground and implemented the guarantees, were ✩46,757. Kudu’s costs, not borne by the project, consisted of salary for the lead programmer and manager of the platform, short-code fees, and radio ads, and totaled ✩58,784. Our platform has three separable components,hydroponic bucket and we consider the business case for each of them in turn. First of these is Kudu.

The core issue for the standalone Kudu model is that, due to limited use of mobile money in rural Uganda, the platform does not have a mechanism to collect commissions on transactions.29 Hence, it appears that the most logical model to make Kudu sustainable would be a user fee model where individuals pay to post bids and asks on the platform. Given a total number of bids and asks of approximately 54,000 and costs of ✩58,000, this fee would need to be approximately a dollar per use. While this is a tiny amount of money relative to the sums transacted in agricultural deals, it is likely that such a fee would sharply curtail use of the system by farmers and lead to paucity of asks. Further, the usage numbers recorded in the study reflect the influence of the finding call center and on-the-ground staff. An alternative business different model would be for Kudu to sell its up-to-the-minute price information. However, to generate reliable and sufficient data, it would have to operate at a massive scale, which presents a chicken-and-egg problem in terms of how to build up to a platform with sufficient scale to make this kind of market information service profitable. Hence, while Kudu represents a substantial potential boon to welfare from market participation, monetizing this benefit is not straightforward. A second component is the SMS Blast system. The costs of collecting the market price data and sending out the SMS Blast was ✩5,857 per month, although as a part of the study we were collecting data on many smaller spoke markets that likely would not make sense from a profit perspective for a commercial system, which may be better off focusing on only larger markets. Our baseline survey asks a question about WTP for market information from traders; the mean stated WTP for an SMS service providing information on spoke, hub, and super hub markets was ✩0.42 per month, indicating that our market information system could have broken even with 14,000 users. Had it been optimized to operate in fewer and larger markets, that threshold would fall. So, while our results do not indicate that price-only systems have large benefits for market participants, this business model may be the easiest to construct. Finally we have the most costly component of the study platform, which is the AgriNet call center, network of CAs, deal coordinators, and monitoring agents to track transactions on the ground.

While this hands-on approach appears to be a necessary part of launching an online trading platform, it is costly and raises the core question of how it can be paid for, given that the core value proposition of the platform to traders and farmers is a lack of intermediation costs on the platform. Given that a) the number of highly profitable trades on Kudu that AgriNet was able to intermediate directly was small, and b) substantial expense is required to put the logistics in place to be able to collect commissions on brokered trades, the project was fundamentally unable to develop a model through which brokerage fees could cover the costs of operating the system. A subscription model would be available either to Kudu or to a market price information system, but intermediation costs seem inherently to be linked to commissions on trade. Therefore, we conclude that this type of intermediary platform is not straightforward to make viable as a commercial enterprise at the scale observed in this study. Our 1,457 sampled study traders were representative of a broader population of 1,752 traders in study districts, meaning that we capture within the study 83% of the people on whom the harm of decreased trading margins fell. Trader profits fell by an average of ✩292 per year, or almost ✩900 over the three years of the study. Therefore study traders lost a total of ✩1.3 million in profits, and the broader sample of which they are representative lost a total of ✩1.53 million. Combined with the direct cost of running the platform, we therefore estimate the social cost of the platform to be ✩2.42 million dollars. The extrapolation of the total farmer benefits from our study sample requires careful consideration. Imprecision issues aside, it is easy to calculate the aggregate the estimated benefit of the intervention to farmers in our study sample. However, because we see evidence that intervention moved general equilibrium outcomes, like total trade volumes and prices, we must consider the effect of the intervention on the broader population of farmers, including those in our study catchment area but who were not sampled in our household surveys.

How can we best estimate the impact of the intervention on this population? First, we focus on treated households that did not receive the Blast, as the Blast was only targeted to a subset of individuals in our study and was not available to the broader population. Second, we estimate effects separately for those in the “Near” village finding, who are representative of a smaller population of households in the more urban village containing the TC, and for those in the “Far” village finding, who are representative of a much larger population of more rural households in the surrounding sub-county.30 To estimate these ingredients, we present in Table A.22 the core farmer impacts broken out by main treatment status, SMS Blast treatment status, and “Near” vs. “Far” LC1 status, with dummies for each of these three categories and full interactions between them. We can then use the coefficients from Table A.22 to calculate the total revenue effect in each of the four relevant strata.31 For the two strata treated by the Blast finding the study sample represents the population experiencing this effect. For the near stratum not receiving the Blast, the study sample of 1,280 should be representative of the 16,297 households in the same LC1s from which they are sampled. For the far stratum not receiving the Blast, the study sample of 567 should be representative of the much larger sample of 919,697 households in all ‘far’ parishes finding. We start by restricting our benefit calculation to the benefit of farmers in our study sample only. For these farmers, we calculate an aggregate benefit of ✩124,000, far less than the costs. However, applying the per-household benefits to the populations for which they should be representative, the outcome in the “Far” Blast control dominates the welfare calculation and drives our estimate of total benefits to farmers to ✩34 million dollars, thirteen times as large as the total social cost finding before declining to 453.0 million MtCO2e in 2009 as the economy slowed finding finding. Agricultural emissions, as a fraction of total net emissions, are also gradually increasing, from 6% in 2000 to 7% in 2009. In 2006, the California legislature passed Assembly Bill 32 finding, the Global Warming Solutions Act of 2006 finding,stackable planters which requires California to reduce greenhouse gas emissions to the 1990 level of 427 million MtCO2e by 2020. This amounts to a 15% reduction in 2008 levels and a 30% reduction in levels that would occur by 2020 if no actions were taken. AB 32 directs the California Air Resources Board finding to develop a plan for reducing greenhouse gas emissions, which the agency completed and made available for public comment finding. The plan identifies emission reduction strategies targeting emission sources for different sectors; nine focus on agriculture finding. The reductions are mandatory for some sectors, such as industrial enterprises and electrical power operations, but for agriculture they are voluntary. Agriculture represents a significant economic sector in California; it uses 25% of the state’s land and consumes about 75% of its water resources finding.

California agriculture produced approximately $34.8 billion in revenue in 2010 finding and ranks number one among states in agricultural cash receipts finding. In terms of greenhouse gas emissions, agriculture accounted for about 7.1% of California’s total in 2009 finding. The Air Resources Board plan for achieving AB 32 goals includes a combination of direct regulations,performance-based standards and market-based mechanisms. The centerpiece is a cap-and-trade program, which would initially target certain production or distribution processes, including cement production, oil refining, and other significant users of fossil fuels. The program is designed to potentially be linked to similar programs, in particular to an envisioned regional cap-and-trade program that includes New Mexico, British Columbia, Quebec and Ontario. Under California’s proposed cap-and trade program, regulated firms would be given allowances for greenhouse gas emissions once a year beginning in 2012, declining 2% to 3% per year to match emission reduction targets. Firms with surplus allowances could sell or save finding them for future use. Firms unable to reduce their emissions or looking to increase emissions could enter the market to purchase surplus allowances finding. These trading features of the proposed program finding are standard components of cap-and-trade systems, including those pioneered in California to reduce air pollution finding. The Board’s proposed program is also innovative because it would be open to additional private or public mitigation activities that reduce emissions or sequester greenhouse gases. Firms or groups in non-capped sectors may undertake mitigation activities and then be credited with offsets. Regulated firms can buy these and use them in lieu of government-issued allowances to meet a portion of their regulatory requirements finding. Firms in capped sectors could also theoretically undertake mitigation activities beyond their quota, depending on their marginal abatement cost. Trading under the cap, and potentially supplementing allowances with offsets, are both expected to reduce compliance costs, an objective of the Board’s plan. The two mechanisms are complementary: trading creates price signals that motivate regulated firms to seek low-cost mitigation opportunities, and the opportunity to earn credits that can be sold encourages regulated and non-regulated firms and groups to seek low-cost mitigations in sectors where emissions are not capped. To work, the program requires a comprehensive set of standards and regulations that details how emissions are measured and offsets created, especially if it is to be part of a regional cap-and-trade system. The standards and regulations must rigorously protect the environmental benefits associated with emission reductions, because regulated emitters have incentives to under-report emissions, and both buyers and sellers of offsets benefit from exaggerated mitigation claims finding. Initially, the Board plan envisions four sets of rules, called compliance offset protocols, for offset-generating projects, including one for livestock projects.

The definition of sustainability offered here places a priority on broad-based equity considerations

The importance and volatility of food prices have made most governments reluctant to let market forces alone set these prices.Thus, a host of institutional measures have been implemented to address agricultural prices in order to manage their effects on consumer welfare, public coffers, farmer income, foreign exchange, food security, nutrition, and food distribution.Such policies include commodity programs, water and reclamation programs, import/export policies, and research and extension programs.Larger economic factors indirectly affect the agricultural system, factors such as interest rates, trade policy and negotiations, the exchange value of the U.S.dollar, and environmental regulations.In the context of these economic policies, agriculture is subject to non-agricultural constraints and conditions, a fact acknowledged broadly in the literature of both conventional and sustainable agriculture.Yet most research and extension programs in both conventional and sustainable agriculture do not recognize or address these macro factors.Sustainable agriculture efforts generally concentrate on environmentally sound farm-level technologies which are economically profitable for farmers to adopt.Less commonly do such efforts address how the technologies they generate will affect or be affected by larger economic concerns in the long run.A second assumption behind many sustainable agriculture definitions, that short-term profitability is of ultimate importance, is also common.This is a central tenet of LISA, forming the first of its ten Guiding Principles: “If a method of farming is not profitable, it cannot be sustainable.”This is problematic, particularly since there is little acknowledgement that profitability is determined by policies, fiscal procedures, and business structures that can obstruct sustainability.We recognize that short-term profit- ability is important in commercial agricultural systems; clearly,hydroponic nft system if growers are to adopt sustainable agricultural practices, these must be profitable in the short run as well as the long run.

The problem lies in pursuit of short-run profitability at the expense of environmental and social goals.In conventional agriculture, the drive to maximize short-term profit has meant that many pressing problems have been ignored or exacerbated.Natural resources have often been treated as expendable commodities , and agriculture has functioned more for financial gain than for human need.The social costs of production have generally been neglected: chronic hunger, inequitable economic returns and unsafe working conditions for farm labor, possible negative health effects related to nutrition and agrichemical use, and the decline of socioeconomic conditions in rural communities associated with large-scale industrial agriculture.Subsuming social goals to economic goals may easily be reproduced in sustainability programs unless sustainability concepts address the fact that profitability and social goals are often not compatible in current economic systems.A useful concept of agricultural sustainability needs not only to acknowledge social issues as priorities equivalent to those of production, environment, and economics, but to recognize the need for balance among those disparate but highly interactive elements which comprise agriculture.Toward this, we offer the following perspective: A sustainable food and agriculture system is one which is environmentally sound, economically viable, socially responsible, non-exploitative, and which serves as the foundation for future generations.It must be approached through an interdisciplinary focus which addresses the many interrelated parts of the entire food and agriculture system, at local, regional, national, and international levels.Essential to this perspective is recognition of the whole-systems nature of agriculture; the idea that sustainability must be extended not only through time, but throughout the globe as well, valuing the welfare of not only future generations, but of all people now living and of all species of the biosphere.This sustainability concept moves beyond emphasis of farm-level practices and micro-economic profitability to that of the entire agricultural system and its total clientele.Richard Lowrance, Paul Hendrix, and Eugene Odum16 describe a model which approximates a whole-systems approach.They see four different loci or subsystems of sustainability: 1) farm fields where agronomic factors are paramount; 2) the farm unit wherein micro-economic concerns are primary; 3) the regional physical environment where ecological factors are central; and 4) national and international economies where macroeconomic issues are most important.

Their model demonstrates that focusing on only one level of the agricultural system neglects others that are equally essential.A whole-systems perspective fosters an understanding of complex interactions and their diverse ramifications through- out agriculture and the systems with which it articulates.This understanding is at the root of sustainability.Vernon Ruttan17 describes an ever-widening comprehension of “whole system” as he delineates three waves of social concerns which have arisen about natural resource availability, environmental change, and human well-being.In the late 1940s and early 1950s the first wave focused on whether resources such as land, water, and energy were sufficient to sustain economic growth.The second wave, in the late 1960s and early 1970s, focused on the effect of growth-generated pollution on the environment.The most recent concerns, manifest since the mid-1980s, also center on adverse environmental effects, but the key distinction is the transnational issues such as global warming, ozone depletion, and acid rain.As agriculture and its impacts become increasingly globalized, the need for a whole-systems perspective, particularly in terms of decision-making, become increasingly critical.Dahlberg 9 observes that although the impacts of modern industrial society are global, the data and analytical tools we use to assess those impacts are limited by national, disciplinary, or sectoral boundaries.Our educational and research institutions tend to mirror this shortcoming,with the result that the larger system contexts of research questions are infrequently investigated and poorly understood.Difficulties in apprehending and resolving problems whose constituents are grounded in several interrelated systems are compounded by the international community’s disparate, competitive political and economic systems.Nations act to promote their own priorities but affect, often negatively, globally shared resources and globally interdependent societies.Although nations and other sociopolitical groups generate impacts beyond their borders, they are generally incapable or unwilling to assess and react equitably to the results of their actions.Pierre Cross on and Norman Rosenberg 18 note the inadequacy of information feedback about significant environmental problems in modern societies, an inadequacy which characterizes feedback about social problems as well.

Accounting for the system-wide implications of local actions should be a primary objective for sustainable agricultural systems.The tools to facilitate such an accounting can only be developed within a whole-systems perspective.We believe it is inadequate to exclude social justice as a priority and that there is an ethical requirement for greater equity in the agricultural system.Some have combined concern for how we treat the environment with how we treat our fellow human beings.For those focusing on the latter, it is essential to look beyond sustaining our environmental and economic ability to produce agricultural goods.It is equally important to ensure that those goods are produced and distributed in an equitable manner.A concern with this human values aspect of agriculture involves a sweeping rather than localized concept of who constitutes “us.” Typically, resource conservation is dis- cussed in terms of its implications for farmers’ profit- ability or our descendants’ food-producing capabilities.The sustainability definition offered in this paper does not limit equity considerations to these groups.A concern with equitable social relations in agriculture requires defining “us” in terms of all fellow humans – not only farmers and future generations, but also farm workers, consumers, non-farm rural residents, Third World urban poor, and others.Sustainability in this sense is framed in terms of both inter generational and intragenerational equity.Thus, issues such as farm worker rights and inner-city hunger are as central as issues of soil erosion and groundwater contamination to the goals of agricultural sustainability.One of the most profound challenges facing agriculture is creating a decision-making process which will fairly resolve equity issues.Such a process must assess competing interests; evaluate agriculture’s costs and benefits,nft channel and the recipients of each; decide fairly what the compromises must be; recognize and encourage shared goals and common ground.In most discussions of sustainability either environmental quality or social justice issues are emphasized, but neither can be sup- ported wholly at the expense of the other.Nourishing humans, ensuring social justice, and providing a reasonable quality of life cannot be accomplished if agriculture’s resource base and environmental constraints are neglected.Likewise, few would argue that environmental considerations should be pursued at the expense of satisfying basic human needs.An equitable agricultural system must foster a decision-making process which is truly democratic, one which identifies not only what the costs and benefits are but how to distribute them fairly among all sectors of society.Many sustainability definitions, particularly those which guide applied sustainable agriculture programs, are based on the primacy of farm production and short-term profitability.

As sustainable agriculture programs have increasingly been incorporated into long-established agricultural institutions they have manifested the largely unquestioned intellectual assumptions and infrastructural constraints which characterize their parent institutions.This is problematic because conventional agricultural institutions have fostered many technologies and policies counter to sustainable agriculture goals.23 Such institutions have, for example, contributed to concentration within agriculture; have not generally benefited agricultural labor; and have systematically failed to examine their impact on the environment, the structure of rural households and communities, and the consequences of rural resident displacement.24 To situate new pro- grams designed to address these problems within the framework which produced them is of questionable value unless steps are taken to change the nature of that framework, for it determines the way its re- searchers see the world, pose questions, and define problems.When agriculture is viewed in a whole-systems context and sustainability is defined comprehensively, it is clear why the current popular focus on farm production practices is insufficient for achieving agricultural sustainability.Developing non-chemical pest management methods, for example, will effectively reduce pesticide use only if economic structures and policies encourage their adoption by farmers.More importantly, one cannot conclude that improved production practices will transform the agricultural system into one that meets all environmental, economic, and social sustainability goals.Social goals must be addressed explicitly.This is why production techniques such as organic farming, while a likely component of a sustainable food and agricultural system, cannot be thought of as synonymous with sustainable agriculture.Given the conventional institutional context of most state and federal sustainable agriculture programs it is not surprising that they tend to focus research on conventional priorities such as production practices and efficiency and have not, for the most part, aggressively addressed social and economic issues.Sustainability priorities – and the definitions which embody them – must be expanded to encompass the many factors affecting production and distribution as well as the larger environmental, economic, and social systems within which agriculture functions.This has been the focus of the Agroecology Program since its inception in 1982.Through conferences and publications* we have worked to expand the discussion and practice of integrating these aspects of sustainability.

Recently, the University of California Sustainable Agriculture Research and Education Program has broadened its agronomic focus to include social, economic, and policy issues.SAREP defines sustain- able agriculture as integrating “…three main goals – environmental health, economic profitability, and social and economic equity.”Their grant program, which encourages research and education on social, economic, and public policy issues affecting food and agriculture, could become a model for other sustain- able agriculture programs such as LISA.We believe that it is important to continue exploring the meaning of agricultural sustainability.Before an improved agricultural system can be developed the biases and structures that have led to agricultural problems must be closely examined and concrete goals articulated, based upon a broadened concept of agricultural sustainability.The concept of sustainability offered in this paper emphasizes that social goals are as important as environmental and economic goals, and widens the opportunity to move beyond the narrow agricultural priorities expressed in the past.It is based upon the whole-systems, interactive nature of all aspects of the agricultural system – that problems and their resolutions must be conceived not only in terms of their immediate time frames and local impacts, but just as importantly, in terms of their future time frames and their global impacts.It encourages emphasis on optimum production over maximum production, the long term along with the short term, the public’s best interest over special interests, and the contextualization of disciplinary work within interdisciplinary frameworks.Our hope is that this definition helps advance the discussion on developing a food and agriculture system that is sustainable for everyone.Global warming attributed to the anthropogenic emissions of greenhouse gases has increased the global temperature by ∼0.89 °C in the 20th century.Approximately 13% of total GHG emissions were contributed from agricultural lands and N2O emission from agriculture accounted for 61% of total anthropogenic N2O emissions.

The limited extent of ownership change may have limited the effects found in this study

Measuring costs per unit of output, the authors find that privatization increased the efficiency of firms operating in both competitive and non-competitive environments, and that the efficiency gains from privatization were significantly greater in non-competitive environments than in competitive ones.These results provide a uniquely controlled setting in which to study the effect of competition on relative efficiency, and also the relative importance of agency issues and soft budget constraint issues in publicly-owned firms.Since public firms should become less relatively less efficient than prive firms as competition increases, because soft budget constraints shield them from competitive pressures, and relatively more efficient as competition increases, because the observable performance of other firms reduces agency issues, the fact that efficiency gains from privatization attenuated with the level of competition provides evidence that the effects of agency issues dominated the effects of soft budget constraints in this study.The study also documents the existence of subsidies to public firms prior to privatization – amounting to 12.7% of GDP in Mexico – suggesting that reductions in agency-related issues due to competition had to surmount substantial soft budget constraint issues that presumably increased with the level of competition that firms faced.Because La Porta and Lopez-de-Silanes separates ownership effects by competition level, examines a large number of firms, and is exceptionally careful and thorough in its approach, it is one of the most persuasive studies in providing evidence of the effects of competition on ownership efficiency.The vast majority of studies that examine public and private efficiency differences in noncompetitive settings are studies of privatization efforts that compare the performance of enterprises before and after state ownership.

A complication in studying privatization programs is that ownership effects could take place gradually,nft hydroponic and might not be adequately captured just after privatization takes place.Additionally, the announcement of a government’s intentions to privatize sometimes preceded the actual transfer of ownership by several years, during which the perception of ownership transferrability and a period of “shake-out”could increase public firm efficiency.Lastly, privatization programs are typically accompanied by other regulatory changes – in particular, many governments shielded state-owned firms from competition, and undertook market liberalization measures either concurrently with privatization, or after a grace period during which newly privatized firms are shielded from competition.Unless these liberalization effects are separated, studies may compare public monopolies to private firms operating with limited competition, and thus conflate the effects of competition and ownership on efficiency.Of the 9 studies in non-competitive environments in our review, 5 study privatizations of telecommunications firms.Within this industry, Wallsten and Boylaud and Nicoletti both find no ownership effects from privatization, while Ros , Ramamurti , and Boles de Boer and Evans find that private firms are more efficient than state-owned firms.Wallsten studies the privatization of telecom monopolies in 30 countries across Africa and Latin America, from 1984 to 1997.Controlling for competition changes and other concurrent programs that may have affected firm efficiency, he finds no effect of privatization on labor productivity in the absence of additional regulatory measures.When privatized firms are faced with price regulation from an independent regulator, though, privatization yields efficiency benefits.This result is consistent with theory: By keeping prices low, regulators essentially create the pressure for efficiency that competition does, which differentially affects private firms if public firms face soft budget constraints.

Boylaud and Nicoletti study telecom privatizations in 23 OECD countries from 1991 to 1997, and similarly conclude that ownership did not affect labor productivity, when controlling for the level of competition and also the time to liberalization.However, both the number of competitors and decreases in the time to liberalization are associated with increases in productivity.The authors interpret the effects of time to liberalization as being due to the effects of potential competition, which may have stimulated managers and employees in public firms to increase efforts to avoid unemployment as profit margins were reduced.Such responses may be partially attributable to an anticipated reduction in cross subsidization across internal groups, which the authors describe as common prior to privatization.However, diminished agency issues would only occur when actual competitors emerged, and the separately significant effect of the number of competitors provides evidence that agency issues are important.Notable in this study is the fact that the government “generally maintained the largest single share of the PTOs capital and sometimes retained special voting rights in the privatised enterprises.”Indeed, some studies find that ownership change is only effective when firms are fully privatized.Ros , Ramamurti , and Boles de Boer and Evans all find productivity improvements in telecom firms following privatization.Ros studies a mix of firms that were either privatized during the period from 1986 to 1995, or were private throughout the period, and measures ownership effects on labor productivity while controlling for competition.Ramamurti finds significant ownership effects in 3 of 4 telecoms studied, but does not separate competition and ownership effects, and acknowledges that the level of competition may have changed after privatization.Boles de Boer and Evans provide a case study of the 1990 privatization of Telecom New Zealand, and study efficiency changes during the period from 1987, when the market was liberalized, to 1993, when the first actual competitors entered.

As a case study, the evidence the auhtors present is inherently less generalizable than that of other studies.On the other hand, the authors are less restricted to use variables that are common across all firms being studied, and can be precise about the levels of competition and other contextual details of the privatization.The study measures productivity as the level of output per cost of inputs, where inputs include labor, material inputs, and capital.They find that productivity increased by 10% per year during the study period, and that unit costs reduced by 5.8% per year.Like Ramamurti , the authors do not separate the effects of competition and ownership in their examination; however, competitors only emerged in the final year of the study, and potential competition due to deregulation was present throughout.A concern permeating all the telecom studies is that the effects of ownership are averaged across both the monopoly conditions and conditions of limited competition following market liberalization, making it impossible to isolate the precise market conditions under which these effects occur.Caves and Christiansen provides some evidence on ownership effects in a static competitive environment, by comparing two Canadian railroads – one private, one state owned – who were each other’s sole competitors for many decades.Measuring the cost of inputs per unit of output, they find that the state-owned railroad was initially less productive than the private one, but find no significant differences between the two by the end of the 19- year study period.Since the railroads began to compete 30 years prior to the study period, their findings suggest that efficiency improvements may take a very long time to adjust to a change in the level of competition.Assuming this is true, the privatization studies that average efficiency effects across short periods of time during which monopolies were exposed to competition may be best placed as studies reporting relative efficiencies under monopoly conditions.Both Caves and Christiansen and Ramamurti make another contribution to the analysis: While they both study railroads that faced little or no direct competition , both argue that the railroads they study faced substantial indirect presure from other forms of transportation that competed for both passengers and freight.Ramamurti explicitly documents the market share of the Argentinian railroad he studies, and finds that only 8% of freight and intercity travel were handled by the railroad, along with 15-20% of suburban travel.Since ameliorating agency issues requires the observation of direct competitors, both studies exist in a non-competitive environment for agency purposes.However, indirect competitive pressure reduced prices and profit margins, and thus expand the efficiency gap between public and private firms due to soft budget constraints.With both unmitigated agency issues and exacerbated soft budget constraint issues, theory would predict the efficiency gap between these railroads to be at their largest.

Indeed, Ramamurti finds that privatization resulted in a 370% increase in labor productivity,nft system and explicitly documents the existence of railroad subsidies to the state-owned Argentinian railroad prior to privatization.Caves and Christiansen, who paradoxically find no significant differences by the end of their study, also point out that the state’s role was “restricted to that of a stockholder”in their study – no subsidies were provided to the state owned railroad.Both of these studies point to the potential relevance of state subsidies in reducing efficiency gains, particularly in environments where firms face substantial competitive pressure.Ehrlich et al conduct a very careful study of 23 airlines with varying ownership types, and estimate a model wherein productivity is endogenously and separately determined for each airline.The authors include several robustness checks using alternate specifications, and do not consistently find level differences between the cost efficiencies of private and public airlines across all specifications.However, they find that private firms have a relatively higher rate of cost reduction over time in each specification that they test.To examine whether ownership effects vary with competition levels, the authors separately test the efficiency of the subset of airlines in the US, Canada, France, and the UK, arguing that that they exist in competitive environments because there are more domestic competitors within these nations.Although the authors find qualitatively similar results for these airlines, it is unclear whether airlines in those four countries might not face very different competitive environments from airlines that are the sole carriers for their countries, to the extent that airlines compete internationally, and also because – as the authors themselves point out – the International Air Transport Association coordinated fares and erected barriers to entry for all airlines during the period of study.Also notable in this study is the fact that both private and public airlines have historically been subject to soft budget constraints via “bailouts”,so that state-owned airlines may not be subject to a widened efficiency gap at higher competition levels in this industry.Funkhouser and MacAvoy study firms in a variety of industries in Indonesia, and compare their efficiencies by computing the ratio of each firm’s average costs to the appropriate industry average.Although they find no differences at the 5% level, private firms are significantly more efficient at the 10% level.Cullinane, Song, and Gray use a method that is increasingly popular in the recent literature to estimate cost efficiency: stochastic production frontier function estimation.Rather than looking at the cost of producing a unit of each output separately, or creating an index to evaluate the cost of all outputs simultaneously, the method establishes an efficient frontier of production using the data available, and evaluates each firm’s efficiency based on its distance from the frontier.The authors study 15 container ports in Asia, and find no significant differences in efficiency based on ownership.Of the 7 studies reviewed that study competitive environments, only 3 found that private firms were more efficient than state-owned firms.Of those 3, Vining and Boardman and Diboky both used measures of efficiency that are sensitive to revenue gains; it is unclear whether the measures used in Chen and Yeh are price-sensitive or not.As the evidence in Section 1.3.1 suggests, the efficiency of private firms may be overstated using price-sensitive measures, when markets are not highly competitive.Diboky and Chen and Yeh are similar in other respects.Both studies use Data Envelopment Analysis to estimate the technical efficiency of public and private firms that contemporaneously exist over the study period.Diboky studies results for 300 insurance firms in Germany that compete directly with each other; Chen and Yeh examine 34 domestic banks in Taiwan that face additional competition from 67 banks that are partially foreign-owned.Diboky measures firm “outputs”as gross premiums and net income, while Chen and Yeh measure quantities of loan services and portfolio investment.Chen and Yeh find that private banks outperform public banks; Diboky finds that public banks were substantially less efficient than either private or “mutual”banks of mixed public and private ownership.Vining and Boardman study a variety of industries whose four-firm concentration ratios vary from 14% to 43%, suggesting that the competitive environment in their study bordered on monopolistic competition, by the standards of this review.In such an environment, their use of efficiency metrics such as sales per employee and sales per asset may have caused private firms to appear more efficient than state-owned firms for reasons of higher prices, rather than lower unit costs.

Agriculture plays a central role in many important and influential hypotheses about human history

Greater effective soil age in little-eroded uplands soils means a longer time for the accumulation of recalcitrant organic matter in older soils—and probably more importantly, it allows the accumulation of noncrystalline minerals that stabilize soil organic matter.We further suggest that the patterns for total P are more complex because its pools reflect both weathering and loss and retention by both organic matter and mineral adsorption, which are greater in the upland slope positions.Overall, these results illustrate that erosion and deposition have a rejuvenating effect on the supply of rock-derived nutrients in these valley landscapes —one that suffices to make both lower slope and alluvial soils fertile enough to support intensive pre-contact agricultural systems in both valleys despite the infertility of the upland soils surrounding them.However,differences in the structures of the valleys influenced their ability to support intensive agriculture prior to European contact.Halawa Valley and other large valleys on older islands have well-developed colluvial aprons surrounding their alluvial floors.In contrast, Pololu¯ Valley lacked the potential for lower-slope rainfed agriculture because the high subsidence rate of Hawai’i Island causes a sharp transition between slopes too steep to cultivate and the nearly flat valley floor —a process that is accentuated by the rapid glacial-melt-driven sea level rise of the past approximately 20 ky.Other major valleys on Kohala Volcano have similar structures—including the largest, Waipi’o Valley, which was a major center of precontact Hawaiian settlement.Considering only the area bounded by the cliff tops on the valley sides and waterfalls at the head of the valleys,flood and drain table differences in subsidence rates and corresponding in-fill histories cause large differences in the distribution of slopes suitable for agriculture within Pololu¯ and Halawa.

Assuming that slopes of less than 5 could have been made suitable for intensive pond field systems, 17% of the 423 ha surface of Pololu¯ Valley could support pond fields ; only 6% of the 692 ha surface of Halawa Valley had slopes less than 5.Further, assuming that 12 represents an upper threshold for intensive rainfed agriculture, 16% of Halawa Valley has slopes between 5 and 12 , as opposed to only 5% of Pololu¯ Valley.Available archaeological evidence for pre-contact agricultural systems in Pololu¯ and Halawa is consistent with our findings on valley topography and soil fertility.Tuggle and Tomonari-Tuggle found evidence for both irrigated and rainfed fields on the flat alluvial floor of Pololu¯.They attribute the fact that not all the Pololu¯ alluvium was irrigated to the valley’s hydrologic conditions; the valley floor is so large relative to its watershed area that stream flow was inadequate to have watered the entire valley floor.In Halawa Valley, the entire area of alluvium was converted to irrigated pond fields, which also extended onto the lower colluvial slopes.More importantly, well-defined rainfed cultivation plots with stone-faced terraces and walls extend well up the colluvial slopes in Halawa, encompassing an area greater than the total area of irrigated pond fields there.Rosendahl mapped the Kapana area of Halawa Valley, providing a detailed example of intensive rainfed agricultural terraces, integrated with habitation sites and small temples.Significantly, mid-nineteenth century land records from Halawa demonstrate that most claimants included both irrigated as well as rainfed areas in their claims , showing that the two kinds of agriculture were integral parts of the overall production system at the household level.The broader implications of this potential for intensive rainfed agriculture on colluvial slopes of the valleys on the older islands in the Hawaiian Archipelago are substantial.Analyses of the distribution of intensive agricultural systems and their consequences for the dynamics of Hawaiian society have considered irrigated and rainfed systems to have been spatially separated, due to the very different ecosystem and landscape properties that favor their development.

Because these types of agricultural systems differ both in their ability to produce a surplus over agricultural labor and in their vulnerability to drought—with both comparisons favoring the irrigated pond field systems—these contrasting systems could have contributed to the development of rather different societies, in areas or on islands dominated by one system or the other.The islands of Hawai’i and to a lesser extent Maui were based largely upon intensive rainfed systems, with only a few well-watered irrigated valleys.In contrast, the older islands in the archipelago have been thought to be based mostly upon irrigated pond field systems.However, the evidence here suggests that the older islands likely maintained integrated pond- field/rainfed systems and that, as in Halawa Valley, the peripheral rainfed systems could have covered a larger area than did irrigated pond fields.A similar pattern has been suggested in the leeward Makaha Valley of O’ahu, where archaeological survey confirmed the presence of extensive areas of dryland gardening on colluvial slopes, but where irrigation was confined to smaller areas in the valley interior.The potential for developing integrated pond- field/rainfed systems on colluvial slopes on the older islands strengthens the contrast between the agricultural production potential of Hawai’i Island versus the older islands.It has been suggested that pressures to maintain surplus production in rainfed, drought-prone agricultural areas could have driven the elites of Hawai’i Island towards marriage alliances with elites of the older islands, and/or towards conquest of those islands —and the development of integrated pond field/rainfed systems on the older islands would only have increased their attractiveness as potential acquisitions.Moreover, integrated systems on the older islands could have boosted their potential agricultural yields, and the diversity of foods they could produce, to levels approaching the total productivity of the much larger island of Hawai’i.These dynamics should be incorporated into our understanding of the dynamics of Hawaiian society, and those of other indigenous societies in which similar dynamics could occur.For the vast majority of our evolutionary history, humans subsisted by hunting animals and gathering plants.

Around 12,000 years ago, we began to take a more direct role in the process of food production, domesticating animals and cultivating crops in order to meet our nutritional requirements.This subsistence revolution is thought to have occurred independently in a limited number of places.This new way of life is arguably the most important process in human history, and its dramatic consequences have set the scene for the world we live in today.Agricultural productivity, and its variation in space and time, plays a fundamental role in many theories of human social evolution, yet we often lack systematic information about the productivity of past agricultural systems on a scale large enough to test these theories properly.Here, we outline how explicit crop yield models can be combined with high quality historical and archaeological information about past societies in order to infer how agricultural productivity and potential have changed temporally and geographically.The paper has the following structure: First, we introduce the ways in which agriculture is involved in theories about human social evolution, and stress the need to scientifically test between competing hypotheses.Second, we outline what information we need to model about past agricultural systems and how potential agricultural productivity and carrying capacity can provide a useful way of comparing societies in different regions and time periods.Third, we discuss the need for a systematic, comparative framework for collecting data about past societies.We introduce a new databank initiative we have developed for collating the best available historical and archaeological evidence.We discuss the kinds of coded information we are collecting about agricultural techniques and practices in order to inform our modelling efforts.We illustrate this task by presenting three short case studies summarizing what is known about agricultural systems in three different regions at various time periods.We discuss the challenges confronting this approach, and the various limitations and caveats that apply to the task at hand.Fourth, we outline how we can combine a statistical approach of modelling past crop productivity based on climate inputs with the kind of historical information we are collecting.The development of agriculture and the ways it has spread and intensified are fundamental to our understanding of the human past.For example, authors such as Renfrew, Bellwood, and Diamond argue that early agricultural societies enjoyed a demographic advantage over hunter-gatherers, which fueled a series of population expansions resulting in agriculturalists spreading out to cover much of the world, taking their culture and languages along with them.At the beginning of the European age of exploration, agricultural societies had pushed the distribution of forager populations in the Old World to only those places that were marginal for agriculture.

Widespread forager populations were present in the Americas and Australia, but these too eventually gave way to agricultural populations of European origin.Agriculture raised the carrying capacity of the regions in which it developed and spread,rolling bench leading to people living at higher densities with a more sedentary way-of-life than was previously possible.However, the development of agriculture did not stop there.Further improvements in agricultural technologies and techniques, and processes such as artificial selection further raised the productivity of agriculture and the size of the population that could be supported in any one region.These improvements ultimately enabled humans to live in large urban conglomerations with extremely high population densities.Influential models of agricultural innovation, starting with the work of Esther Boserup , argue that advances occur in response to increases in population, and the subsequent decreasing availability of land.This drives farmers to invest more labor in producing food.In other words, there is feedback in the system that leads to the increasing intensification of agriculture.These processes of intensification, whatever their cause, can occur in a number of different ways and have had important consequences.From the fields and hedgerows of Northern Europe to the mountainside rice terraces of the Ifugao of the Philippines , through to the deforested slopes of Easter Island , agricultural populations have dramatically altered the landscapes around them.Agriculture is central to many theories about how larger-scale complex societies evolved.Under functionalist views of social complexity more productive agricultural systems allowed for ‘surplus’ production, and enabled a more extensive division of labor.This surplus production allowed for individuals who did not grow their own food, enabling the creation of specialized managers and rulers, and occupational artists and artisans.It is argued that this division of labor increases efficiency and coordination, enabling more complex societies to out-compete less complex societies either directly or indirectly.Under this view, not only is a rich resource base a necessary condition for the emergence of complex societies, but it is also a sufficient one.If this is correct, it follows that differences in agricultural productivity can explain why some regions developed more complex societies than others.Changes in agricultural intensity have also been linked to changes in the ritual and religious life of human groups.It is argued that hunter-gathers and early agriculturalists, who lived in small groups and faced high risks from hunting of large animals, tended to participate in dysphoric, “imagistic” rituals that, although rarely experienced, are typically emotionally intense.Such rituals act as a mechanism for creating social cohesion via ‘identity fusion’.A greater dependence on agriculture led to increased group sizes, and required different forms of cooperation and coordination in order to successfully produce food.New ritual forms developed that were organized around daily or weekly cycles but with less intense emotional experiences.It is argued that this ‘routinization’ enabled strangers to recognize and identify with others as members of a common in-group, enabling trust and cooperation on a hitherto unknown scale.It is clear that agriculture is of fundamental importance to studies of the human past.The ideas outlined above represent just a flavor of the ways agriculture and agricultural productivity enter into our understanding of the long-term patterns and processes of human history.

Importantly, these ideas are hypotheses that require testing against other plausible narratives.For example, it has been argued that an important factor driving the evolution of complex societies was intensive forms of conflict between nomadic pastoralists and settled agrarian societies that selected for increasingly larger and more cohesive societies.Thus, complex societies tended to emerge on the border of the Eurasian Steppe and spread out from there.Under this view, agriculture is seen as necessary but not sufficient to explain the observed variation about where and when such societies developed.When attempting to understand the past we should seek to test between competing hypotheses, rather than simply focusing on a single favored idea.In order to do this, it is important to have relevant data on past agricultural systems and their productivity and potential.These systems exhibit a great deal of variation, and are of varying levels of intensity.To enable more direct comparisons across different regions and time periods, it will be important to have explicit models that translate different agricultural systems across space and time into a common currency.This will allow us to perform statistical analyses so that we can directly test alternative hypotheses.

Some specimens could only be identified to the family level

Since its colonial introduction to the Old World, the golden berry also has been referred to as the cape gooseberry; however, Physalis peruviana from South America is marketed in the United States most commonly as golden berry and sometimes Picchu berry, named after Machu Picchu in order to associate the fruit with its origin in Peru and to address the fact that this fruit is not actually a gooseberry as the name cape gooseberry implies. As a member of the plant family Solanaceae, it is closely related to the tomatillo . High in Vitamins A, B, and C, as well as phosphorus and protein, golden berries also have a range of documented medicinal uses, including antitussive, antihelmintic, antidiabetic, and diuretic properites; they are also used to combat a range of maladies from eczema to conjunctivitis to gonorrhea . Recent studies have discovered 14 new compounds in various species of wild tomatillo that have anti-cancer properties; these compounds, known as withanolides, are already showing promise in combating a number of different cancers and tumors without noticeable side effects or toxicity . Passion fruit/maracuyáis a woody perennial climbing vine that originated in Brazil and then spread throughout South America. Cultivated in humid and dry climates, passion fruits can be grown up to 1,500 masl, but require non-flooded land with good drainage to produce successfully. Both the fruit pulp and seeds of this sweet fruit are consumed as desserts, and the fruits are also squeezed into juices and made into salsas. Similar to cotton, passion fruits can be pressed for oil, which is used to aid digestion. Passion fruits also possess magical and medicinal properties; they are used an as anaphrodisiac , as well as a muscle relaxer and sedative . Cactus fruits of the genus Opuntia are abundant in the Moche Valley today; this plant grows between 500 and 3,000 masl in interandean valleys and survives in soil with low to medium soil fertility. The pulp of the cactus fruit is consumed also has a variety of other uses, including medicinal ; cosmetic ; to attract cochineal insects used for dyes; and as fodder for livestock .

In addition, various wild plum or wild cherry/cerezospecies are distributed throughout Peru, wild and cultivated up to 3,500 masl, with known comestible and medicinal uses .A number of other miscellaneous/wild taxa were identified in the assemblages,vertical grow rack including various weedy taxa found in agricultural fields and on habitation sites, many of which have known economic uses . Others likely represent incidental inclusions, unintentionally transported to the site in the clothing of family members and fur of livestock returning from agricultural fields. In contrast to field cultigens and tree crops that produce large seeds or rind fragments, many of the miscellaneous/wild species discussed below have not received much treatment in the Andean archaeological literature. Only in the past few decades have paleoethnobotanists made attempts to systematically identify small weedy seeds from archaeological samples , in contrast to the recovery of larger taxa hand-picked during excavation or from larger mesh/screen sizes that characterize earlier excavation techniques.Some of these families are represented by multiple genera and hundreds of species, so it is difficult to make specific inferences about their economic uses by Moche Valley residents. Some of these families are well adapted to disturbed environments and occupy agricultural fields , in open uncultivated areas , or on rocky hill slopes or other relatively undisturbed areas . Other species identified to the species or genus level have well-documented economic uses, with data from ethnographic studies and some have longer histories of use evidenced archaeologically. Many of the taxa discussed below had multiple uses, including as food, medicine, fodder, fuel, or other purposes, with different portions of plants used for different purposes, including with different preparation methods . I draw primarily on ethnobotanical uses discussed by Brack Egg , along with other scholars cited below. Food taxa in the miscellaneous/wild category include amaranth/kiwicha 17, lupine/tarwi , mesquite/algorrobo , plantain/Plantago spp., oregano , purslane/verdolaga , rattlepod/crotalaria , saltbush/orache , sow thistle , trianthema , vetch/haba , wildbean and a member of the genus Rubus. Some of these comestibles are fairly well known; for example, amaranth is fairly cosmopolitan in cuisine, as a nutritious grain that can be toasted, popped, ground into flour, or boiled for gruel . Native to Peru, amaranth is distributed throughout the Andes from Colombia to Argentina, on the on the coast, highlands , and high jungle.

Both wild and cultivated , different species of amaranths grow within different elevation zones, with coastal varieties that can be grown up to 500 masl and altiplano varieties up to 4000 masl . Brack Egg lists two wild species that can be grown in the north coast region . Amaranth has long been used as a food source in the Andes, including by the Inka , with archaeological evidence of cultivation going back as far as 2,000 years, recovered in tombs in northwestern Argentina . It is also used as livestock fodder and has medicinal uses, including to treat diarrhea, sore throats, menstrual cramps, and rashes. The green leaves also be can be eaten like vegetables . Mesquite, or algarrobo , is another well-known food; ripened seed-pods are often ground into flour and also used to make chicha. The seed pods also serve as camelid fodder. The sweet, molasses-like flavor of mesquite is incorporated into many beverages in Peru today, including algarrobina, a cocktail that uses mesquite syrup extract. Thriving in alluvial and rocky soils up to 1,500 masl, mesquite trees grow quickly and are long-lived . Their hardwoods are a source of long-burning firewood and charcoal as well as a raw material for wooden tools . The leaves, greens, and seeds of many of the miscellaneous/wild taxa may have been eaten raw or cooked, including lupine, plantain, purslane, saltbush, rattlepod, Rubus spp., sow thistle, vetch, and wildbean, while others were used as seasoning or condiments, such as oregano or trianthema . Some of these taxa have moderate to high degrees of toxicity and must be processed, e.g., lupine, which has a high alkaloid content. A member of the Fabaceae family, lupine, or tarwi, is typically considered to be a ‘highland’ food, as it grows up to 3,850 masl . A number of the miscellaneous/wild taxa have known medicinal uses as well, including acacia/faique , amaranth, knotweed/smartweed , milk thistle/cardo , oregano, purslane, ragweed/ambrosía , rattlepod, saltbush, sedge/piri-piri , spurge , tillandsia/achupalla , sage/salvia , shoreline purslane/capin , sida/pichana , vervain/verbenaand violet/violeta .

These plants have known analgesic properties and been documented for the their use in treating a range of maladies, from coughs/colds, headaches/earaches/throat aches, gastrointestinal distress, rashes, and menstrual cramps, among others, and also have been used in fertility management as contraceptives or abortive agents . Certain taxa, e.g., vervain, have known uses in veterinary medicine as well; used to treat cattle hooves in the Andes today , it is possible that vervain could have been used to treat prehistoric ungulates . Certain spurges that have known purgative properties, along with sedges that have aphrodisiac properties have documented uses in shamanic rituals as well . Some of the miscellaneous/wild taxa also have known fuel uses, including tillandsia, saltbush, mesquite, and acacia. A few archaeological studies have identified plant taxa and other organic materials including woods and other herbaceous plants used as prehistoric fuels on the north coast , for cooking, firing ceramics, and working metal. In Inka times, fuel was an important tribute item . Beyond potential inventories of north coast fuels, the social relations associated with fuel use remain poorly understood. Moche Valley residents likely burned dung as a source of fuel in addition to grasses and tree fuels . In order to identify dung burning archaeologically, Wright suggests that researchers consider the following: if there is a basis for using dung such as a shortage of available wood, the presence of suitable dung-producing animals in the archaeological context considered, recognizable animal dung in the archaeological deposits,vertical grow table and the recovery of such samples from hearth contexts . No wood analysis was conducted in this dissertation, so it is difficult to say at this point if there was a shortage of any particular taxa in the Moche Valley that would have been used for fuel. As discussed further below, seeds of the potential fuel taxa only were recovered in small quantities, but future wood charcoal analyses may reveal a different pattern. The Moche Valley does not have the dense stands of algarrobo trees witnessed in the more northerly Jequetepeque Valley ; I imagine that Moche Valley residents likely used a combination of gathered wild plant taxa and dung as fuel sources.

Camelids would have served as suitable dung-producing animals; indeed, ample amounts of dung, from camelids as well as guinea pigs, or cuy , were recovered throughout the Moche Origins Project excavations at MV-224, MV-225, and MV-83, and was present in many flotation samples . Hastorf and Wright and Miller and Smart argue that animal dung can serve as a vector for seeds from fodder plants, e.g., Poaceae, Chenopodiaceae, Verbenaceae, and Boraginaceae, taxa that were present in the Moche Valley assemblages. A number of the miscellaneous/wild taxa were likely used for animal fodder as well, including amaranth, grasses including crown grass/gramaloteand panic grass/grama , lupine, rattlepod, sandbur/pega pega , sida, tillandsia, trianthema, vetch, and wildbean. All of these taxa have ethnographically documented cases of fodder use for livestock . Brack Egg lists sida in particular as a fodder used for guinea pigs. However, as Wright identifies, separating taxa used for fodder from taxa used for human consumption is complicated. Fodder can often be the same species as food used for human consumption and may also be processed and stored in a similar fashion . Ethnographic data suggest that the boundary between food and fodder is flexible and often depends upon the success of the harvest. In other words, what might be fodder in one year, could be used for human consumption the next year if yields of more preferred foods are low. This distinction even relates to fodder and fuel; for example, the preferred economic use of tillandsia is as fuel, but it can also serve as a fallback fodder for animals . Finally, some of the miscellaneous/wild taxa have other technological uses, as construction materials, for matting/thatching , textile production, etc. Sage and field madder have documented uses as green/yellow or red dyes, respectively . Other taxa may simply be the result of incidental inclusions in the archaeobotanical assemblages, and may not have been used by Moche Valley residents. The archaeobotanical assemblages from the five Moche Valley sites include a combination of wild and cultivated plants, with ecological requirements in many cases involving anthropogenic intervention. Moche Valley farmers had sustained access to water from irrigation canals, resulting in the creation of a landscape of cultivated fields, orchards, and fallow pastures.

Aside from a wide range of field cultigens and tree crops , other fruits would have been actively managed, likely lining fields. A number of miscellaneous wild species thrive in areas disturbed by humans and likely existed and were harvested in gardens even if not intentionally grown. Certain economic weedy species thrive along irrigation canals ; in disturbed areas ; and in fields under cultivation or recently fallowed , presenting Moche Valley farmers with opportunities to collect them while managing farming tasks. Ethnographic and Ethnohistoric Perspectives of Food Preparation and Processing Some materials and techniques of processing and preparation of plant foods recorded in ethnohistoric documents and witnessed today may have some bearing on past practices. Many of the edible plants and animals listed in the inventories of prehistoric sites in Peru are still grown, purchased, or gathered today, and while I do not assume an unbroken continuity for two millennia regarding the ways in which foods were processed and prepared, ethnographic and ethnohistoric sources are a useful starting point for thinking about the organization of food ways. Throughout South America, the practices of baking in ovens or frying over fires were virtually unknown in prehispanic times . While much literature has focused on Inka or highland traditions rather than coastal valleys, a small amount of ethnographic and ethnohistoric information is available for the north coast region.

Agricultural pesticides are often detected in rural homes

A related anaerobic process is nitrate-dependent iron oxidation; a recent review has highlighted, in the context of this process, how the simultaneous presence of nitrate-reducing and iron-reducing areas can potentially be important to nitrogen cycling.Under anaerobic conditions, iron can also be linked to ammonium oxidation.If reactions that generate N2O are active in any of the above processes, they may be stimulated or suppressed by different forms of iron, such as the two indices examined in this study.The degree of this influence under different conditions will then determine the importance of iron relative to other soil properties.Our treatments consisted of two contrasting values for soil moisture and addition of amendments.This was done in order to explore the importance of iron across a wide range of conditions while at the same time avoiding a cumbersome dataset.It is clear from Figure 1 that the importance of iron can change between the two limits of each treatment variable.For example, between 50 and 100% WHC under ammonium fertilization, iron moves from a position of modest relevance to become the highest-ranked driver.Since our results show the importance of iron only at two distinct values, we do not know how its importance under intermediate conditions changes between the two end values.Even without such intermediate data, the differences between contrasting treatments can aid in understanding the mechanisms at work in generating N2O.In the above example, the importance of iron rises markedly under ammonium fertilization as soil moisture increases from 50 to 100% WHC; FeP surpasses FeA in strength as well.

As mentioned earlier, ammonia is oxidized to hydroxylamine, and this can react with iron to produce N2O.In a wetter soil,dutch buckets solutes are more mobile, which can lead to greater production of hydroxylamine as well as greater contact of hydroxylamine with iron.FeP is also likely to be more soluble than FeA.Any combination of these effects might elevate the importance of iron and change which form is more relevant in explaining the associated N2O data.The overall position of iron among other drivers of N2O emission is determined by both its reactivity and the presence of processes subject to its influence.Ample opportunity for inquiry exists for defining the extent of the relationship between iron and N2O in managed as well as unmanaged ecosystems, and this can provide useful practical and theoretical information.For example, including iron in current models of N2O emission may strengthen their predictive ability.In addition, inasmuch as certain indices of iron can be related to its physical or chemical characteristics, observing the relationship between a given index and N2O production, and how this changes under different conditions, may provide insight into the specific reactions at work.As stated earlier, production of N2O is generally accepted to be a microbial affair, and it is logical to assume that the factors that regulate the activity of N2O-producing microorganisms should be the same factors that regulate N2O production.This is not incorrect, but is perhaps a somewhat restrictive rendering; a more accurate framework might include ‘‘biotic-abiotic reaction sequences’’that generate N2O, such as those outlined above.Indeed, ‘‘the complex interactions that occur between microorganisms and other biotic and abiotic factors’’ have been suggested to be a key part of further understanding greenhouse gas production and improving predictions.Pesticide drift, which is the off-target movement of pesticides, is recognized as a major cause of pesticide exposure affecting people as well as wildlife and the environment.In the United States in 2004, > 1,700 investigations were conducted in 40 states because of drift complaints, and 71% of the incident investigations confirmed that drift arose from pesticide applications to agricultural crops.Pesticide drift has been reported to account for 37–68% of pesticide illnesses among U.S.agricultural workers [California Department of Pesticide Regulation 2008; Calvert et al.2008].Community residents, particularly in agricultural areas, are also at risk of exposure to pesticide drift from nearby fields.

Alarcon et al.reported that 31% of acute pesticide illnesses that occurred at U.S.schools were attributed to drift exposure.The occurrence and extent of pesticide drift are affected by many factors, such as the nature of the pesticide 2010], equipment and application techniques , the amount of pesticides applied, weather , and operator care.Pesticide applicators are required to use necessary preventive measures and to comply with label requirements to minimize pesticide drift.Pesticide regulations such as the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act and EPA’s Worker Protection Standard require safety measures for minimizing the risk of pesticide exposure , and many states have additional regulations for drift mitigation.Better understanding about the magnitude, trend, and characteristics of pesticide poisoning from drift exposure of agricultural pesticides would assist regulatory authorities with regulatory, enforcement, and education efforts.The purpose of this study was to estimate the magnitude and incidence of acute pesticide poisoning associated with pesticide drift from outdoor agricultural applications in the United States during 1998–2006 and to describe the exposure and illness characteristics of pesticide poisoning cases arising from off-target drift.We also examined factors associated with illness severity and large events that involved five or more cases.Participating surveillance programs identify cases from multiple sources, including health care providers, poison control centers, workers’ compensation claims, and state or local government agencies.They collect information on the pesticide exposure incident through investigation, interview, and medical record review.In California, on some occasions, such as large drift events, active surveillance is undertaken for further case finding by interviewing individuals living or working within the vicinity affected by the off target drift.Although the SENSOR-Pesticides program focuses primarily on occupational pesticide poisoning surveillance, all of the SENSOR-Pesticides state programs except California collect data on both occupational and nonoccupational cases.In California, PISP captures both occupational and nonoccupational cases.SENSOR Pesticides and PISP classify cases based on the strength of evidence for pesticide exposure, health effects, and the known toxicology of the pesticide and use slightly different criteria for case classification categories.This study restricted the analyses to cases classified as definite, probable, possible, or suspicious by SENSOR-Pesticides and definite, probable, or possible by PISP.

We also performed analyses restricted to definite and probable cases only.Because the findings from these restricted analyses were similar to those that included all four classification categories , only the findings that used the four classification categories are reported here.In this study, a drift case was defined as acute health effects in a person exposed to pesticide drift from an outdoor agricultural application.Drift exposure included any of the following pesticide exposures outside their intended area of application: a) spray, mist, fumes, or odor during application; b) volatilization, odor from a previously treated field, or migration of contaminated dust; and c) residue left by offsite movement.Our drift definition is broader than U.S.EPA’s “spray or dust drift” definition, which excludes post application drift caused by erosion, migration, volatility, or windblown soil particles.A drift event was defined as an incident where one or more drift cases experienced drift exposure from a particular source.Both occupational and nonoccupational cases were included.An occupational case was defined as an individual exposed while at work.Among occupational cases, agricultural workers were identified using 1990 and 2002 Census Industry Codes : 1990 CICs, 010, 011, 030; 2002 CICs, 0170, 0180, 0290.Figure 1 presents the process of case selection.We selected cases if exposed to pesticides applied for agricultural use including farm, nursery, or animal production, and excluded cases exposed by ingestion, direct spray, spill, or other direct exposure.We then manually reviewed all case reports and excluded persons exposed to pesticides used for indoor applications , persons exposed within a treated area , and persons exposed to pesticides being mixed, loaded, or transported.Drift cases therefore represented the remaining 9% and 27% of all pesticide illness cases identified by the SENSOR-Pesticides and PISP, respectively.We also searched for duplicates from the two programs identifying California cases.Because personal identifiers were unavailable, date of exposure, age, sex, active ingredients, and county were used for comparison.A total of 60 events and 171 cases were identified by both California programs.These were counted only once and were included only in the PISP total.Drift events and cases were analyzed by the following variables: state, year, and month of exposure, age, sex, location of exposure, health effects, illness severity,grow bucket pesticide functional and chemical class, active ingredient, target of application, application equipment, detection of violations, and factors contributing to the drift incident.U.S.EPA toxicity categories ranging from toxicity I to IV were assigned to each product.

Cases exposed to multiple products were assigned to the toxicity category of the most toxic pesticide they were exposed to.Illness severity was categorized into low, moderate, and high using criteria developed by the SENSOR Pesticides program.Low severity refers to mild illnesses that generally resolve without treatment.Moderate severity refers to illnesses that are usually systemic and require medical treatment.High severity refers to life-threatening or serious health effects that may result in permanent impairment or disability.Contributing factors were retrospectively coded with available narrative descriptions.One NIOSH researcher initially coded contributing factors for all cases.Next, for SENSOR-Pesticides cases, state health department staff reviewed the codes and edited them as necessary.Any discrepancies were resolved by a second NIOSH researcher.For PISP cases, relatively detailed narrative descriptions were available for all incidents.These narratives summarize investigation reports provided by county agriculture commissioners, who investigate all suspected pesticide poisoning cases reported in their county.After initial coding, the two NIOSH researchers discussed those narratives that lacked clarity to reach consensus.Data analysis was performed with SAS software.Descriptive statistics were used to characterize drift events and cases.Incidence rates were calculated by geographic region, year, sex, and age group.The numerator represented the total number of respective cases in 1998–2006.Denominators were generated using the Current Population Survey micro-data files for the relevant years.For total and nonoccupational rates, the denominators were calculated by summing the annual average population estimates.A nonoccupational rate for agriculture-intensive areas was calculated by selecting the five counties in California where the largest amounts of pesticides were applied in 2008.For occupational rates, the denominators were calculated by summing the annual employment estimates including both “employed at work” and “employed but absent.” The denominator for agricultural workers was obtained using the same 1990 and 2002 CICs used to define agricultural worker cases.Moreover, in California, where data on pesticide use are available, incidence was calculated per number of agricultural applications and amount of pesticide active ingredient applied.Incidence trend over time was examined by fitting a Poisson regression model of rate on year and deriving the regression coefficient and its 95% confidence interval.Drift events were dichotomized by the size of events into small events involving < 5 cases and large events involving ≥ 5 cases.This cut point was based on one of the criteria used by the CDPR to prioritize event investigations.Illness severity was dichotomized as low and moderate/high.Simple and multi-variable logistic regressions were performed.Odds ratios and 95% CIs were calculated.To our knowledge, this is the first comprehensive report of drift-related pesticide poisoning in the United States.We identified 643 events involving 2,945 illness cases associated with pesticide drift from outdoor agricultural applications during 1998–2006.Pesticide drift included pesticide spray, mist, fume, contaminated dust, volatiles, and odor that moved away from the application site during or after the application.

Although the incidence for cases involved in small drift events tended to decrease over time, the overall incidence maintained a consistent pattern chiefly driven by large drift events.Large drift events were commonly associated with soil fumigations.Occupational exposure.Occupational pesticide poisoning is estimated at 12–21 per million U.S.workers per year.Compared with those estimates, our estimated incidence of 2.89 per million worker-years suggests that 14–24% of occupational pesticide poisoning may be attributed to off-target drift from agricultural applications.Our study included pesticide drift from outdoor applications only and excluded workers exposed within the application area.Our findings show that the risk of illness resulting from drift exposure is largely borne by agricultural workers, and the incidence was 145 times greater than that for all other workers.Current regulations require agricultural employers to protect workers from exposure to agricultural pesticides, and pesticide product labels instruct applicators to avoid allowing contact with humans directly or through drift.Our study found that the incidence of drift-related pesticide poisoning was higher among female and younger agricultural workers and in western states.These groups were previously found to have a higher incidence of pesticide poisoning.It is not known why the incidence is higher among female and younger agricultural workers, but hypotheses include that these groups are at greater risk of exposure, that they are more susceptible to pesticide toxicity, or that they are more likely to report exposure and illness or seek medical attention.However, we did not observe consistent patterns among workers in other occupations.This finding requires further research to identify the explanation.

Young women were clearly identified as high-risk targets for SH

Gender harassment was reported by 30% of female crew members, of which 9% also reported unwanted sexual attention and 1% reported sexual coercion. The relative prevalence of these SH categories mirrored the pattern in prior California studies, although the rates of workers reporting SH in our study were considerably lower than the rates reported in those studies . This may be explained by regional and crop-specific differences. For example, working conditions in Napa vineyards are generally considered better than those in other agricultural sectors, with workers offered above average wages and benefits . Additionally, we considered harassment only at a worker’s current company, not throughout the worker’s overall agricultural or working career, which could have resulted in a lower reporting rate compared to previous studies. The low rates of unwanted sexual attention and sexual coercion in our study were far lower than those found in other studies. Such low rates reflect well on the Napa industry, but they may also, despite the anonymity of responses, indicate a reluctance among women to admit severe harassment when participating alongside co-workers and in a study coordinated as we did this one. The small number of women reporting unwanted sexual attention or sexual coercion meant we were not able to consider an analysis of the relationship between the severity of SH with the other variables measured. Instead, we focused on two types of group comparison based on the presence or absence of SH: women reporting any type of harassment versus women reporting no harassment, and crews where SH was reported versus crews where SH was absent . We analyzed average scores or counts except for crew gender ratio, SH awareness training and relatives in crew. For these three variables, we classified female participants into additional groups based on the percentage of females in a crew, the percentage of crew members that were SH-trained and the presence or absence of relatives in a crew. Thus, female participants were assigned either to a low-female group or a high-female group and either to a low-SH-trained group or to a high-SH-trained group , using a median split.

Descriptive data for harassed and non-harassed female participants show that harassed women in our study differed on two antecedent variables. As in other industries ,what is a vertical farm harassed women were significantly younger than non-harassed women; women under 40 years of age accounted for two-thirds of reported harassment cases in our study. Second, 89% of women reporting the more severe categories of harassment were seasonal employees. More female seasonal workers than permanent workers reported gender harassment, although this relationship was not statistically significant . Harassed and non-harassed women did not differ significantly in the presence of relatives on their crews, the duration of their employment, crew size, crew gender ratio or the number of members in their crew that had received SH awareness training . Harassed women had significantly higher turnover intentions and lower overall job satisfaction compared to non-harassed women, supporting prior research on the negative impact of SH on morale and worker productivity. We compared descriptive data for SH+ and SH− crews on hostile sexism and male work outcomes. Mean scores for hostile sexism were significantly higher in SH+ crews compared to mean scores in SH− crews, supporting the theory that sexist attitudes contribute to a climate of SH tolerance . This complemented our finding of a higher incidence of gender harassment over other types of SH. The hostile sexism questionnaire can thus be considered an attitudinal measure of the behavioral gender harassment component of the SEQ, as hostile sexist attitudes appeared to be enacted as behavioral harassment towards women workers. Turnover intentions for male members of SH+ were significantly higher and job satisfaction was lower than they were for males in SH− crews. We could not determine whether dissatisfied male workers were more likely to perpetrate SH or if witnessing SH adversely affected male workers; however, the latter has previously been concluded in other research .

We identified several variables associated with the presence of SH in agricultural work crews, and we demonstrated that SH is associated with a decline in work outcomes. The type of design we employed in this study cannot verify causation between variables, only association. However, these statistical associations, together with consideration of the literature on SH in other industries, provides grounds for healthy speculation as to how agricultural companies might address SH among their workers.The oldest woman reporting SH was 47; most harassed women in this sample were 40 years or younger. Despite the lack of statistical differences in SH incidence between seasonal and permanent female workers, the severe forms of SH were overwhelmingly reported by seasonal workers. While recognizing that all workers are at risk of SH, companies should therefore be especially vigilant of the risk to young and seasonal female workers.Changing the structure of work crews is unlikely to reduce SH. In our study, harassed women worked in crews that were large and small, with or without relatives, and with considerable variation in gender ratio. Harassed women were just as likely to be working on crews with a high percentage of females as on crews with a low percentage of females . This was unexpected, as meta-analyses have demonstrated gender ratios to be a significant predictor of SH . However, the gender ratio effect may be small, and as SH occurs in a range of organizational settings , the characteristics of SH perpetrators may be more important. For example, perpetrators in male dominated workplaces tend to be co-workers, whereas perpetrators in female-dominated workplaces are more likely to be supervisors . The questionnaire we used in our study did not ask women about the perpetrators, but the unimportance of crew gender ratio indicates the possibility that SH may have originated not only from inside the crews but from outside, such as from supervisors or other company employees. Our presumption that the crew level is the most relevant company unit for SH was too optimistic. We often observed multiple crews working in the same vineyard, and they often mixed during work breaks; SH could therefore have originated from other crews, especially as the SH reported in our study was primarily verbal and gestural in nature.

Crew membership was also probably more fluid than our study design conceived. Women were asked about SH only during their current employment, but these women did not necessarily work continually in the same crew configuration. If gender ratio is an important antecedent of SH in agriculture, we predict it will be at the level of the company rather than at the level of the work team.Our results, as supported by the literature , indicate that an improvement in organizational climate is a more effective method for tackling SH than a restructuring of work crews. The hostile sexist attitude of both men and women in a crew was significantly associated with the presence of SH. Companies can expect to reduce SH by changing or neutralizing these attitudes. However, shifting these attitudes may be difficult to accomplish, as indicated by our finding that previous SH awareness training was not related to a decrease in reported SH. Similar poor efficacy of SH awareness training has been reported in prior research , suggesting that improvements are needed to the structure and administration of awareness training for agricultural workers. Unless these changes are made, other organizational climate variables, such as the internal management of complaints and the overall social climate of a company , are more likely to be effective in reducing SH. There is still value in conducting training, as it has been shown to make women more likely to report SH and it makes workers more aware of what is acceptable behavior . Since we did not collect details on which training programs the workers received, we cannot comment on the efficacy of one training program over another. Harassed females reported lower job satisfaction and higher intention to quit their jobs, illustrating that SH is likely resulting in companies losing female workers and experiencing other negative effects associated with poor worker satisfaction. The same reduced outcomes were reported by male workers in crews where harassment was occurring, suggesting that SH may be impacting not only the targets but also the co-workers. Dissatisfaction among men as a result of SH thus also has the potential to negatively affect company performance. The current study demonstrated that workplace sexual harassment of female vineyard workers affects the well being and retention of all workers in an agricultural sector where there is a paucity of quantitative data on the issue. Furthermore, this study illustrated that female workers in entry positions to the industry are most at risk of SH, illustrating that SH is a barrier for women seeking to enter the agricultural workforce. Thus, SH has the potential to significantly affect the stability of the labor pool in a time of labor shortage and to incur economic costs not only for workers but also for agricultural organizations seeking to train and retain stable work crews. Incidence of SH in our study was lower than that previously reported for farm workers, but our results should be treated with some caution; there may have been some under reporting due to our method of data collection and our relatively small sample size. This study also measured SH in one region and one crop only, and incidence rates may not generalize to other agricultural regions and sectors. Workplace policies and practices that reduce or eliminate hostile sexist attitudes appear to have the most promise for reducing SH in agriculture. However,vertical strawberries vertical system accomplishing these goals with limited resources and within a company’s traditional organizational structure may be challenging.

Future studies may seek to consider in more detail how organizational climate can be effectively addressed in the agricultural sector, the effectiveness of different SH awareness programs and the characteristics of perpetrators of SH towards women. In response to a shift toward specialization and mechanization during the 20th century, there has been momentum on the part of a vocal contingent of consumers, producers, researchers, and policy makers who call for a transition toward a new model of agriculture. This model employs fewer synthetic inputs, incorporates practices which enhance biodiversity and environmental services at local, regional, and global scales, and takes into account the social implications of production practices, market dynamics, and product mixes. Within this vision, diversified farming systems have emerged as a model that incorporates functional biodiversity at multiple temporal and spatial scales to maintain ecosystem services critical to agricultural production. This essay’s aim is to provide an economists’ perspective on the factors which make diversified farming systems economically attractive, or not-so-attractive, to farmers, and to discuss the potential for and roadblocks to widespread adoption. The essay focuses on how a range of existing and emerging factors drive profitability and adoption of DFS, and suggests that, in order for DFS to thrive, a number of structural changes are needed. These include: 1) public and private investment in the development of low-cost, practical technologies that reduce the costs of production in DFS, 2) support for and coordination of evolving markets for ecosystem services and products from DFS and 3) the elimination of subsidies and crop insurance programs that perpetuate the unsustainable production of staple crops. This work suggests that subsidies and funding be directed, instead, toward points 1) and 2), as well as toward incentives for consumption of nutritious food. Each year, more than 50,000 people in the U.S. die from hospital-acquired bacterial infections, millions experience episodes of food borne illness, and reported cases of “superbugs” such as Methicillin-resistant Staphylococcus aureusand vancomyc in-resistant enterococci are on the rise. For those who acquire a resistant infection in their food, in their community, or in a hospital, resistance is associated with a longer duration of treatment, the use of more potent antibiotics, and longer hospital stays. This, in turn, means increased health care costs and costs to society due to antibiotic-resistant infections. Antibiotic resistance is contributing to the scope and severity of this health care crisis, and at least some of the responsibility for antibiotic resistance sits on the shoulders of industrial livestock production. In livestock operations, low or sub-therapeutic doses of antibiotics are used to promote growth, in addition to their use to prevent and control disease. Today, more antibiotics are used in livestock production and the production of milk and eggs than in humans. While the use of sub-therapeutic doses of antibiotics is regulated less stringently in the United States than in the European Union, there is movement toward and potential for such regulation.

Agricultural mechanization is the use of any mechanical technology and increased power to agriculture

The implication is that increases in agricultural production have to be met through increases in agricultural productivity, and less through expansion of cultivated area. Another worsening factor is the climate change and global warming. Some studies predict that global warming will significantly and negatively affect African agriculture. They also indicate that the use of irrigation reduces the harmful impact of global warming. In addition, irrigation use is a catalyst of improved technology adoption, which will have a substantial impact on food security.The author’s understanding of food security is informed by Sen’s entitlement theory. Farmer’s access to food can be seized either through the output markets or through increases in productivity levels and improvements in food storage. As elicited by the “sell low, buy high” puzzle, the mark-up is usually very high and a significant number of households in rural Mozambique may not afford to purchase food during the lean season. Therefore, it becomes crucial to enhance both agricultural productivity and farmer’s ability to store food. Selective mechanization, improved storage, and other improved agricultural technologies play an essential role in ensuring farmers’ food entitlements. Previous attempts to mechanize the agricultural sector in the post-colonial period have failed, one of the reasons being the 16-year civil war that started a year after the independence in 1975. Moreover, the government established tractor-hire schemes had serious planning,vertical grow shelf management, and training problems, denting the image of agricultural mechanization in general. Agricultural mechanization is also mistakenly perceived as tractor mechanization.

This includes the use of tractors, animal-powered and human-powered implements and tools , as well as irrigation systems, food processing and related technologies and equipment. Although not addressed in this paper, the use of jab planters has been shown to significantly reduce labor requirements. Information on the economic impact of selected improved agricultural technologies is needed to target interventions efficiently and equitably, and to justify investment in such technologies.This paper assesses the impact of improved agricultural technologies by constructing a counterfactual comparison group. In this setting, a comparison of the outcome variable is made between farmers using a given technology and their counterparts with similar observable co-variates .The use of tractor mechanization is significantly correlated with road infrastructure. The distance to the nearest tarred road is three times higher among households who did not use tractors, relative to their counterparts. Remarkably, among the 2 percent of the population that used a tractor, 49 percent accrues to Maputo province, and 32 percent to Gaza province, both located in the south, a region of relatively lower agricultural potential, but of better road infrastructure. The remaining 19 percent are distributed across the other 8 provinces, which includes agro-ecological zones of higher agricultural potential, but relatively poorer road infrastructure. Unsurprisingly, adoption rates rise with increases in both landholding size and livestock flocks for all four improved technologies. Households with larger landholdings will potentially have higher production and thus feel compelled to invest in improved granaries. The use of animal traction or tractor mechanization is also cost-effective in larger fields. Additionally, the adoption of animal traction and tractor mechanization require some initial investment, and asset endowment is positively and significantly correlated with household welfare.

With regard to access to credit, the difference between treated and untreated households was only significant for the adoption of tractor mechanization, and marginally significant for the use of animal traction. This result, however, is an artifact of a low data variation as not many households could access the emerging rural credit market. Furthermore, a tractor can be used as collateral, a bottleneck for many rural households in accessing to the credit market. Membership to farmers’ association is also significantly correlated with the use of improved agricultural technologies. The number of farmers using tractor mechanization is three times higher among members of an association. Similarly, there are twice as many farmers using improved seeds among members of a farmers’ association.Figures 1A through 4A show the distribution of propensity scores for all four technologies. Treated and untreated households overlap very well, suggesting that the overlap assumption is plausible. Additionally, the assessment of the overlap assumption was complemented by the analysis of normalized differences. The results are presented in Table 2, and they show that normalized differences are in general smaller than 0.25 . Exceptions are the variables on head’s age and tropical livestock units. However, this outcome did not affect the estimation results because these two variables were dropped from the stepwise logit model due to their low explanatory power. The results on the stepwise logit model are not reported to save space, but are available from the author upon request.Table 4 presents the estimation results of the impact of selected improved agricultural technologies, contrasting the results obtained through three econometric approaches. With the exception of animal traction, the impact of improved agricultural technologies is consistently positive and significantly different zero. The impact is greater for tractor mechanization, followed by the use of improved seeds, and finally the use of improved granaries. Farmers that used animal traction and experienced losses in 2004/05 agricultural season may be enticed to abandon such technology, especially if they rented the animals and the implements. This is probably one of the reasons why “adoption rates” of improved agricultural technologies are usually very low: some farmers abandon the technology after some unsuccessful adoption attempts. Policies to sustain adoption of improved agricultural technologies should be put in place. Irrigation investments fall in that category.The significance of improved granaries underscores the relevance of post-harvest losses, and reducing these losses potentially results in higher household income in light of opportunities for inter-temporal price arbitrage; and improved food entitlements and farmer’s nutritional status. The author speculates that the benefits from an improved granary might outstrip by far its construction costs, considering that it will be used for more than a year.

The impact of improved seeds on maize is about 2 000 Meticais/ha, and 5 180 Meticais/ha for tractor mechanization . The estimates of the impact can also be regarded as shadow prices. Specifically, during the 2004/05 agricultural season, the use of tractor mechanization would be profitable for the farmer whenever the market cost of hiring a tractor was below $212/ha. Likewise, the market price of improved maize seeds required to sow 1 hectare of maize should be lower than $80. Taking into account that mean household income in 2004/05 was about $137 per adult equivalent , and that less than 5 percent had access to credit, understanding why adoption of improved technologies is extremely low becomes trivial. Even if improved agricultural technologies were riskless, a bulk of farmers would not be financially capable of investing in such technologies, much less irrigation. There is certainly an ample scope to enhance the impact of improved seeds and tractor mechanization, considering that less than 5 percent use irrigation or inorganic fertilizers, and about half of the tractors used in Mozambique are located in Maputo province, and more than 3/4 of all tractors are located in the south. If the Mozambican government wants to achieve the much talked-about green revolution, then huge investments on basic infrastructure and irrigation may pave the way for higher adoption rates and profitability of improved agricultural technologies. The bad news is that climate change and global warming is a translucent reality, potentially with severe implications to African agriculture. In the Mozambican agriculture context, the implication is that any effort to foster adoption of animal traction, improved seeds, tractors, and other improved technologies should be accompanied by investments on irrigation or water conservation technologies. Furthermore, drought-tolerant improved seeds will also significantly increase both agricultural production and productivity amidst low irrigation use and recurrent drought spells across the country.Hundreds of reports and articles begin with a variation on the same apocalyptic exhortation: The combination of population growth, food price volatility,vertical hydroponic and climate change demands a new agricultural revolution to expand and secure the global food supply. The bio-technologies frst deployed in the Green Revolution are still being constantly improved; food prices, however, stay stubbornly high and many fear a yield plateau. The new revolution, they argue, is digital technology. In a recent article about the use of artifcial intelligence in agriculture, for example, Wired gushed about “an explosion in advanced agricultural technology, which Goldman Sachs predicts will raise crop yields 70 percent by 2050” . Goldman, for their part, estimate that digital agricultural technologies will become a $240 billion market by 2050 . X, Google’s “moonshot” venture, recently hailed the arrival of “the era of computational agriculture” . Traditional agribusinesses have found themselves competing with Silicon Valley giants, venture capitalists, scrappy startups, intergovernmental organizations, non-governmental organizations , and research institutions to develop and market a dizzying array of new technologies to feed “the next two billion” and save the world. “Digital agriculture” is a heterogeneous suite of information-rich, computationally-complex, and often capital-intensive methods for improving the efficiency of agricultural land and the profit margins of sectoral actors.

Digital technologies have come to play a role in every stage of the agricultural cycle under capitalism, from input management to marketing produce, pricing commodities futures to pest control. However, while it is true that these technologies increase efficiency, we contest the notion that they will provide a long-term solution to the looming crises of the global food system. For what the narrative of an agricultural techno-revolution elides is how the methods of industrialized food production create these challenges in the frst place. We interpret the rise of digital technologies in agriculture as the continuation of a process dating back to the Green Revolution, namely, to reconfigure agrarian life in a manner amenable to increased profits, especially for actors further up the value chain. For the proponents of digital agriculture, the transition is between two technologically-paved pathways to profit: innovations in high dimensional computing supersede innovations in breeding. A purely technological perspective is insufficient and depoliticizes analyses of far-reaching changes to agricultural production, changes which have an effect on the rest of the capitalist economy . Nevertheless, this has not stopped digital agriculture’s boosters from frequently claiming that it heralds a “fourth agricultural revolution.”1 However, digital agriculture has received limited critical attention from social scientists. The vast majority of critical work on the ascendancy of global technology mega-firms and new information-centric accumulation strategies looks at their effects in non-agrarian industrial and service sectors. However, the generation of profits in these sectors depends in part on keeping inputs for production and reproduction— like food—artifcially cheap . By perpetuating an unsustainable regime of cheap food, digital agriculture technologies support the continued expansion of an equally unsustainable global urban system.We argue that the rise of digital agriculture is emblematic of an intensifying relationship between zones of agrarian production and extraction on the one hand, and zones of agglomeration, industrial production, and service provision on the other. A body of neo-Lefebvrian scholarship describes these apparently distinct zones as co-constitutive, entangled in a dialectic of extended and concentrated urbanization . In this framework, the growth imperative of capitalism requires the transformation of vast landscapes beyond the ‘city’ to increase extraction and agricultural output, the product of which is drawn back inward to fuel growth. In this reading, the socio-metabolic process of urbanization is increasingly generalized, to the point that some have argued for thinking of contemporary urbanization as a ‘planetary’ process. With this in mind, this article interrogates the political economy of digital agriculture and reinterprets the digitalization of the food system through the lens of extended–concentrated urbanization. We begin by introducing digital agriculture and the limited social scientific literature on the topic. Next, we critique the mainstream rhetoric surrounding digital agriculture, which makes a Malthusian argument for the need to feed a burgeoning global population in the face of climate change. Then, beginning from the observation that the crucial role of information is under-analyzed in the extended–concentrated urbanization framework, we build a theoretical argument for how digital agriculture challenges the urban–rural binarism. We locate the framework’s origins as a reaction to earlier threads of globalization theory, which emphasized the supposedly immaterial nature and deterritorializing effects of information and communications technologies .